Europaudvalget 2007-08 (2. samling)
KOM (2008) 0019
Offentligt
548808_0001.png
JEergy
Fraunhofer U)5titute
Systems and
Innovation Research
cQi7QflflcS
rjfVUP
ECOFYS
Economic anaVysis of reaching a 20%
share of renewable energy sources in
2020
Annex I to the final report:
Methodological aspects & database
for the scenarios of
RES
deployment
Mario Ragwitz Fraunhofer 1SF
Gustav Resch, Thomas Faber - EEG
August 2006
by order of the:
European Commission
DG Environment
ENV.C .2/SER/200510080r
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0002.png
TaNe of Contents
A. 1.General methodology of the model Green-X 2
A. 2. Development of the cost-resource curve for RES-E, RES-
H and RES-T 2
A. 3. The data requirement 2
A. 4. Calculation of electricity, heat and biofuel generation
costs 2
A. 5. Assessment of the potentials for RES 2
A. 6. Assessment of & overview on the economic data for RES 2
A 7. Calculation of the dynamic cost-resource curve 2
A. 8 Data for the dynamic aspects 2
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0003.png
A. i.Gerieral methodology of the model Green.X
The computer model
Green-X
is an independent sof1iare tool developed under
Microsoft Windows by EEG in the EC-funded project Grcen-X (5th FWP DO
Research, Contract N°: ENG2-CT-2002-00607).' Two major variants of the Gnen-X
model are currently available:
o
An extended variant with respect to the intra-sectoral coverage was developed,
which includes besides RI3S-E endogenous modelling of
all conventional
power
generation options
of the
electricity sector (mel. interconnections and according
restrictions). Geographically this variant covers solely the EU-IS. It allows a
comparative, quantitative analysis of interactions between RES-E, conventional
electricity and CHP generation, demand-side activities and 01-JO-reduction in the
electricity sector, both within the ELI-I 5 as a whole, as well as for individual member
states.
An extended variant with regard to the geographical and scetoral coverage for
RES. It covers besides the EU-IS all new member states (EU-IO) as well as the
EU candidate countries Bulgaria, Rornania and Croatia. It enables a comparative
and quantitative analysis of the ftmture deployment of RES in all energy sectors (i.e.
electricity, (grid-connected and non-grid) heat and transport) based on applied energy
policy strategies in a dynamic context. In this context, the impact of the conventional
supply portfolio within each sector is described by exogenous forecasts of reference
energy prices and corresponding C02 emission-factors etc., all set on countLy level.
For the purpose of this study, the modelling approach has been extended by the concept
of a cross-sectoral quota: The key approach in the ca[cvlations is that the European
energy market optimizes the additional generation costs for R.ES against the background
of a RES target which can be set on a yearly base up to the
year
2020. This overall
optimization is modelled by comparing the difference between RES generation costs and
conventional reference prices across all sectors (heat, electricity and biofuels), all
technologies and all countries. Results are presented in terms of additional costs, that is,
the total costs of generation per energy output minus the refeience cost of energy
production per unit of energy output. To avoid underestimation of the resulting cost with
regard to an enhanced RES-deploynient, negative additional cost are not counted ic. set
to zero. The optimisation is conducted across all three sectors (RES-E, RES-H arid RES-
T). As biomass may play a role in all sectors, the allocation of hiomass resources is a key
issue. Consequently the overall optimization across sectors includes an integrated
optimization of the distribution of bioniass aniong the
sectors.
For more clet&Is see:
h.p:fJjygreen-y..at
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0004.png
Within the model
Greeii-X,
the most important
RES-E
(e.g. biogas, biomass, biowaste,
wind on- & offshore, hydropower large- & small-scale, solar thermal electricity,
photovoltaics, tidal & wave energy, geothermal electricity), RES-H technologies (e.g.
biomass - subdivided into log wood, wood chips, pellets, district heating - , geothermal
and so]ar heat) and RES-T options (e.g. traditional biofuels such as biodiesel and
bioethanol, advanced biofuels as well as the impact of biofuel imports) are described foi
each investigated countiy by means of
dynamic cost-resource
curves.
Dynamic cost
curves are chaiacterised by the fact that the costs as well as the potential for electricity
generation / demand reduction can change each year. The magnitude of these changes is
given endogenously in the model, i.e. the difference in the values compared to the
previous year depends on the outcome of this year and the (policy) framework conditions
set for the simulation year.
In most analysis conducted with the model
Greeji-X
an economic assessment takes Place
on the basis of the dynamic cost curves derived and scenario-specific conditions like
selected policy strategies, investor and consumer behaviour as well as primary energy
and demand forecasts. Within this step, a transition takes place from generation and
saving
costs
to bids, offers and switch
prices.
It is worth mentioning that time policy
setting influences the effective supporE e.g. the guaranteed duration and the stability of
the planning horizon or the kind of policy instrument to be applied.
Policies that can be selected are the most important price-driven strategies (feed-in
tariffs, tax incentives, investment subsidies, subsidies on fuel input) and demand-driven
strategies (quota obligations based
on
tradable green certificates
(including
international
trade),
tendering schemes). All the instruments can be applied to all RES technologies
(and conventional options within the EU-i
5)
separately for the various energy sectors. In
addition, general taxes can be adjusted and the effects simulated. These include energy
taxes
(to
he applied
to
all primaiy energy carriers as well
as
to electricity and heat) and
environmental taxes on CO-emission as well
as policies supporting
demand-side
measures. As
Grceii-X
is a dynamic simulation tool, the user has the possibility to
eJiange policy and parameler settings within a simulation run (i.e. by yeal). Furthermore,
each instrument can
be
set
for each country individually.
Note
that in the least-cost analysis conducted in this study a policy neutral modelling
approach has been chosen. This nicans that no specific
support policies are
assumed,
Modelling results
are
derived on a yearly basis by deterniining the equilibrium level of
e.g. tradable
green
supply
and demand
within
each
considered market segment
certificate market (TOC, both national and international), electricity powem' market and
tradable emissions allowance market. This means that the supply foi' the different
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0005.png
technologies is summed up within each market and the point of equilibrium varies with
the demand calculated.
A
broad
set of results with respect to RES can be gained on country and technology-
level:
total energy output by sector (RES-E, RES-H, RBS-T), by country, by technology
total installed capacity by sector (RES-E, RES-H, RES-T), by country, by technology
share on gross domestic electricity / heat / transport fuel production or demand3
o
average generation costs by sector (RES-E, RES-H, RES-T1, by country, by
technology
import / export balance for the power sector (only for EU-15 countries),
impact of simulated energy policy instruments on supply portfolio, generation costs,
etc.
impact of selected energy policy instruments on total costs and benefits to the society
(consumer) - premium Price clue to RES-E / RES-l-l
I
RES-T strategy.
The latter option is not used in the RES2O2O study.
Table 1: Main characteristics ol the Green-X model
The most important RES-E included
The most important RES-FI included
The most important RES-T included
Geographical aggregation
Encluded policies:
Price-driven strategies
(not used in the RES2O2O study)
thcluded policies:
Demand-driven strategies:
(not used in the RES2O2O siucly)
l3iogas, bioniass, biowaste, wind on & -
offshore, hydropower large & small-scale,
solar thermal electricity, photovoltaics,
tidal & wave energy, geothermal electricity
Biornass, geothermal, solar thennal, heat
PLL11)S
l3iodiesel, bioetjianol, Advanced
bioethanol, BtL
Country level, EU -25
feed-in tariffs, tax incentives, investment
subsidies, subsidies on fuel input
Quota obligations based on tradable green
certificates, tendering schenies
A. 2. Development of the cost-resource curve for
RES-, RS-H and RES-T
A (static) cost-resource curve shows the correlation bei:wecn electricity (respectively heat
and hiofuels) costs per unit and the cumulative amount of electricity (respectively heat
and biofuels) production froni one specific technology in one country per annum. 1-lence,
the development of a cost-resource curve implies knowledge of the Iwo items explained
above:
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0006.png
costs for electricity (or heat) per unit;
total quantity of electricity (or heat) that can be generated per annum at certain
cost levels, The cumulated sum of these amounts is equal to the totally available
potential of a certain technology.
The procedure for deriving the dynamic cost-resource curves is exemplarily depicted in
Figure 1 for the electricity sector. The starting point is the
input-database supply
for
the
first year under investigation.
The database contains information about already existing power plants (at the end of
2001) as well as possible new plants. The outputs of the database are cost-resow'ce
curves for each category containing information with respect to actual generation costs
and the possible potential for electricity generation for the year under investigation.
.rnpu!O!baa Cupply
.1
twcumen(
cutu.
Ol
.1
1
0yom-bao
Oupply
Ew(gpuntu
-
* JuIniue uuEu.
OM
co.fuulcoLuyearn
nfl1
ouLidIy
--.:,.
Econonc mnI
ouppycurva
Erisffug wtanLr
Offor(bidpriceaM
4 01 chquunhiy your
0
• àtmitiuI
tiudJCi1y
_____
_____ *
:OPM1io0
I
• N1rp1u1F.
..- -.
-- *
iFnt'mLmhI
coIo. O&M 1 -
ra
0-0
Supply and
demand
curve
D,io1naIiun oF
vaciooo
Dosound
I
I
OeM
I
In1orclluu oF
:-ceuuYoirn
-..-
-
• -
-
cIiEocoOLOyouro
•O/.
1uriIiulyuiro
rhnoloim,
mrnodullusaud
thClr mTk0tu
SIukoFFdor buhO.wUr
Exolnp bumuu
:. 0ynunif-AooumoI
coIu yeIr
oil
Ariepluloepolonlm!
•PollcyFrnpaut.
ad0&n(00l
°PP°
_____
_____
: -
:goc•Fc..
-
.
Sxlomak(1F.0
-'.
.
n0iiI 0ncur
fl
I
-
+
9uII LIP Of io p1
Dalabaee Supply
- -
llmpril cóuo. 0CM
colt
rOlro+t
• ArM.
riid-Icmr
1
I
r
e oid Co1
-
- --
I
Figure 1 Overview of creatinq dynamic cost-resource curves f-or electricity
geration
At the end of the simulation i-wi for the year n-i , the input database for the following year
will be cicated by adapting the input database for the year a.
This adapted input-database serves as a starting point for the dynamic cost-resource curve
development for the next subsequent year.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0007.png
Note that in the RES2O2O study an overafl optimisation is made across afl sectors.
Therewith one overall cost-resource curve is specified that includes all RES-E, -1-I and -T
options.
A 3.The data requirement
Jnfonnation for the development of dynamic cost-resource curves must be available on
different levels. In general, three levels of data are required in the model Grcen-X,
namely: Country-, technology and band-level. The data requirements at each level will be
briefly outlined below.
The interaction of countty-specific, technology-specific and band-specific data is
indicated in Figure 2 below.
Ce
Tcy1e
BaMLl
oh1*ç'.
i
£2
I
--ai-
I
(nS.
Figure 2 Overview of different levels of supply-side data
Country-specific
data
is characterised by the fact that these values and l)ara!lleters are
valid for all considered technologies in the specific region. Of course, variations occur in
a dynamic context - i.e. from year to year. Country-specific data is swnmarised in Table
2.Despite the fact that the parameters are given exogenously, dynamic effects can be
expected because values are available
as
time-series from 2002 to 2020 in the database.
Technology-specific data is valid and equivalent for all investigated regions. Of course,
changes occur over time and data refers only to a certain technology, see Table 2.
Band specific data are introduced as it is assumed that most of the parameters (data) ai'e
not constant within a region and technology, respectively. I.e. they may vary depending
on the sub-technologies (e.g. combined cycle or steam turbines), energy efficiency
standards, the fuel
input,
the location of the plant, oi the full-load hours, Therefore, it is
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0008.png
V.
necessaty to create several bands within each RES-E & RES-H categoiy, Bands are
characterised by the same economic, technical, social and geographical conditions.2
In the practical implementation, the supply-side database consists of two sub-bases,
namely:
Database: Existing plants
Database: New
plants
Aim of the input-database existing plants' is to provide generation costs for electricity or
heat, respectively, as well as the potential for this generation from bands (plant) which
are already
ii
operation in the investigated year a. Possible new generation options of the
year a are described in the database new plants'. The required band-specific information
is sunitnarised for both categories in Table 3.
Equivalent to the conditions at the other levels, parameters can differ over time.
Table 2: Summary of supply side country-specific data
Pam meter
Country level
Population, land size, GDP (per capita)
Fuel prices for renewable primary energy carriers
Conventional electricity / heat prices (for each
Sector)
Specific (iHO-emission by energy carrier
Grid extension constraints
Mai'ker. transparency
Investor behaviour
I
interest rate
Willingness to accept new plants
Technology level
Lifespan of technology
________
Payback time
Dynamic cost development by technology
(i.e. global projections with regard to development
and technological leanting)
Growth ale industry
_________________
Grid
CStCnSiOi)
cOflsti'aiflts
Market_transparency
Investor heliaviotir / interest rate
Willingness to accept new plants
Aim
To receive comparative results among the countries
To calculate electricity generation COStS
Reference prices - To calculate additional costs for society
due to the promotion of RlS-E & RlS-l4
To derive additional generation costs due the
C02-
constraints and the coflsideration of cxternali tics
for clyntiiii ic palameter asscssmcnl
for dynamic parameter assessment
For dynamic parameter assessment
For dynamic parameter assessment
Aim
__________
To derive date oidecornmissioning of the plant
To derive generation costs cia new
plant
l'o derive investment costs for the year ,i4-l
For dynamic parameter assessment
For dynamic paruneter_assessment
For dynamic paranicter assessnicnt
For cLymiamnic parameter a.sscssniciil
Ior clymuimniic pcmraiueter assessment
Same fuel inputs, sub-technologies, energy efficiency standards, full-load hours, etc.
Investor behaviour depends on various factoms such as e.g. support scheme, planning horizon, technology.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0009.png
Table 3 Summary
bandspecific data
Parameter
Technology parameter
Construction year
Full-load hours elecir.
Full-load hours heat
(in case ofClIP / district heat)
Efficiency electricity generation
___________________________________
Valid for existilig
(Ex) / new (New)
pIats
(iii) i
Aim
output (Out) data
lIlflLJl
Ex
Ex and New
Ex and New
__________________
In
In
in
__________________
Ex and New
[n
Efficiency heat geneottion
Ex and New
In
______________________________
Fuel category
Ex and New
lu
To estimate date ofdccommssioning4
To calculate electricity generation costs
To calculate generation costs
(for clectricity and heat)
To calculate generation costs and
emissions; (his is a dynamic parameter
which changes for new plants
To calculate generation costs and
emissions; (his is a dynamic parameter
which changes for new plants
To calculate generation costs and
emissions; link with fuel p11cc (country
database), mark if fuel switch possible
Table 4 provides an overview of the cost and potential parameters used to specify the
cost/potential curves in the
Green-X
model.
Date ofdecoiniaissioning for a specific plant depends on the lifespan of (lie technology. If the year of
decommisaJoning is reached, the plant will be deleted from (he databaso.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0010.png
Table 4 Parameters used to specify costs and potentials
Potential parameter
Mid-term potential of electricity New
generation ___________________
In Mid-term potential electricity generation
Dynamic restriction
new pLants
Potential of electricity
generation yearn:
Cost parameter
New
lii
Link with dynamic restriction calculation
tool
Ex and New Out Value represents the maximum
electricity generation of the band in year
11
To calculate generation costs; this is
a
dynamic parameter, i.e. inveslmen costs
are adapted year by year
Operation nd maintenance costs Ex and Nw In
To calculate generation costs; this is a
dynamic
parameter,
i.e.
an adaptation of
this parameter
takes
place year by year
_ (link to investment costs)
_____________________________________
_________________ ____________
Fuel category
Ex and New In
To calculate generation costs and
emissions; link with fUel price
(country database)
______________________________
_____________
Payback time
Ex and New
Parameter set at the technology level. hut
information necessary on band level for
various calculations
Interest rate
New in Parameter set at the coirntrv and techn
level but information necessary on band
level for various calculations
Short-term marginal generation Ex Out
Generation costs for existing pLants,
costs
important input for economic assessment
____________________ ______________ ____________ ______
Long-term marginal generation l3x Out
To
calculate profit of the invOslor
costs
(ycar_orcomistnictiomm)
__________________ _____________________
_____________________________________________
Long-term marginal generation New Out
Generation costs for new plants;
costs
import aol input for economic assessment
(year oiconstruetion)
Investment costs
New5 In
A. 4. Ca!cuatIon of eiectrcity, heat and biofuel
generation costs
For calculating the generation costs a distinction must be made between already installed
capacities and potentially new plants. For existing plants, only the running costs (short-
term marginal costs) are ielevant for the economic decision whether the plant should be
used for electricity (or heat) generation or not, while for new capacities, the long-term
marginal costs are important.
A fuither distinction has
been
applied in the following: Generation costs are explained
separately for pure power
&
heat generation options, CHP and district heating.
Note: Invest meni costs for
existing
plants must also
be
available for their date ofconstrmicmioni.
Note: Information must also be available for existing plant for their year of construction.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0011.png
Existing plants
Yearly running costs consist of two parts: fuel costs and operation & maintenance
(O&M) costs. Fuel costs depend on the fuel price of the piiinaiy energy carrier and the
efficiency. O&M costs are set as annual expenditures.
Apart from all kinds of biornass (biogas, solid biomass, sewage and landfill gas),
renewables have zero fuel costs, so running costs are determined by operation &
maintenance costs only.
In the case of simultaneous electricity and heat generation, electricity generation costs are
calculated by considering the revenues gained from the selling of the heat.
New plants
Generation costs pure power (or heat) generation
The calculation of the generation costs of electricity (respectively heat of new plants
consists of two parts, variable costs and fixed costs. In more detail, the generation costs
are given by:
Fixed costs occur independently whcther the plant generates electricity (respectively
heat) or not. These costs are determined by investment costs (1) and the capital recovery
factor (CRF).
Investment Costs and technological improvements
The invesfment costs differ by technology and energy source. As most RES.-E
technologies (with the exception of(targescale) hydropower) are still not mature,
investment costs decrease over time. This evolvement is taken into consideration in the
toolbox GriX, i.e. investment costs are adapted yearly.7
in principle, the model is prepared to include two different approaches on technology
level: (I) standard cost forecasts or (ii) endogenous tcchnologica.l learning (local vs.
global). I-lance, default settings for RES-E & RES-l-l technologies are applied as
indicated in Table 5.
The 'yearly' dctcrL motion 01 he mvcstmncnt
costs represents an
important inpm to the data-tables
described in the previous section, In more detail,
the
tbllowing paramaclel' must
be
derived
lhr each con n(m
and technology
accorclimig
to the
given
situation br the year n-I arid the year
ii:
quantitative values
for
investment
costs
over
tinie.
o quantilative values
for the development
of the efficiency over time.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0012.png
Table 5: Overview of the methodology to dynamicaJy derive investment costs
by technology8
Dynamic cost development
______________________________________
___
________________________________
Biomass electricity (heat, CUP)
-
l3iofuels for transport
__________________________________
Geothermal electricity (hst, CHP)
Geothermal heat non-gtid
Small scale hydropower (<10 MW)
Large scale hydropower (>10 MW)
Landfilgas
Sewage g
Photovoltaics
Solar thermal e1ectrt'
Solar thermal heat
Tidal energy
Wave energy
Wind on-shore
Wind off-shore
___________
-
_______________
Methodology to derive investment costs year
ii
(default settings)
learning curve approach
learning curve approach & forecast based on expert
judgpent (depending on technology)
forecast based on expert judgement & learning cureve
approach
learning curve approach
learning curve pproach
forecast based on expert judgent
forecast based on expert judgement
learg curve approach
learning curve pproach
learning curve approach
learning curve approach
forecast based on expert udgenient
foi'ecast based on expjudgement
learning curve approach
leartng curve roach
_____________
________________
__________________
_________________
______
______
_________
Capital recovery factor CRE
The CRF allows investment costs incurred in the construction phase of a J)lallt to be
discowfled. The amount. depends on the interest late and the payback time of the plant.
hi general,
expeuielice
CurVeS
(ICSCLIbC hOw
costs declinc with cumulative
procliictwn.
In many cases
empirical analysis
have proven
!liat costs decline by a constant
percentage
with each doubting of the units
produced or installed, respectively. Iii general, an experience curve is expressed as fohiows:
C10,
where:
Cr
Costs per wilt as a function of output
Co Costs of the tirst unit produced or installed
GUM Cumulative production over time
b Experience hides
Thereby, the
cxperieiice index
(h,) is used to describe the icttitive
Cost
reduction i.e.
(i-2°.J
-- for cacti
doubling of
the cumulative
production. The value
is
called the
progress ratio tPIQ
of cost reduction.
Progress ratioS or their pendant, the
learning rifles
(i/l)
- Ic.
1.R'l.Pl?
-
arc used
to express the progress of
cost
reduction
for
di1Thrcn technologies. lhcncc_ a progress
ratio
0185%
means
that costs per unit
are
reduced by
5%
for each time
cum
ii
1st ive production is doubled
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0013.png
For the standard calculation of generation costs these factoi's are set for all technologies
as follows:
• payback time (PT) of all plants: 15 years
• interest rate (z equals
6.5%
In the toolbox
Greeii-X
different interest rates are used. The interest rate depends on
stakeholder behaviour and is a function of
guaranteed political planning hoi'izon
• promotion scheme
(not
used in the RES2O2O study)
• technology
iuaiket sector (i.e. private, residential, tertiary sector)
kind of investor.
Note, as the generation costs are catculated per energy output, the fixed Costs must also
be related to the generation of energy. Hence) the fixed costs pci- unit output are lower if
the operation time of the plant - characterised by the thU load-hours - is high. In general,
no taxes are included in the various cost-components.
Generation costs
-
CHP
Deriving the generation costs for Ci-IP plants is similar to the calculation for plants only
producing electricity. Beside the short-terni marginal costs, Le. the variable costs, fixed
costs must be considered for new plants.
Of
course, equivalent to the case for existing
plants, variable Costs differ between CE-TP and conventional electricity plants, as the
revenue from purchasing the heat power must be considered in the first case.
Generation costs
-
biofue/s
Biofuel costs calculations take into account the current entire biofliel production chain
until the distribution at the fuelling station. The production chains for biofuels include the
cultivation and hai-vesting ofbiomass feedstock, transportation to the conversion plant,
biofu els conveis ion and distribution.
A.
5..
Assessment of the potentia!s for RES
The Gra'n-X model differentiates between different types of potentials. Following types
are of ni ai n inipo rtance:
Realisable potential:
The realisable potential represents the maximal acliic-vable
potential assuming that
all
existing baniers
can
be overcome and all driving forces
are active. Thereby, general parameters as e.g. market growlh rates, planning
constraints al-c taken into account. rt is iml)ortant to mention that this potential teim
must be seen in a dynamic context •--
i.e.
the realisable potential has to refer to a
certain year;
Mid-term potential:
The mid-tei-m potential as indicated in Figure 3 is equal to the
i-eat/sable potent/a! in the yeai- 2020.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0014.png
Theoretical potential
w
C
U
U
Mid-term
potential
,,
--
0
upt02020
•0
carriers
Dynamic
0
U
potential
techno!ogy,
society)
Drivers
(policy,
society)
(market,
industry,
additional
realisable
potential
up to 2020
-
\
\
1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
Figure 3 Methodology for the definition of potentials
Below, values are presented for the achieved potential for 2004 and the future potentials for
2020 for renewable electilcity, heat and transport fuels.
RES such as hydropower or wit-id energy are energy sources characterised by a natural
volatility. Therefore, in order to provide accurate forecasts of the future development of
RES-E, historical data for RES is translated into generation potentials - the
achieved
potential
at
the end of 2004. This data was derived in a comprehensive data-collection -
based on (Eui-ostat, 2006), (TEA, 2006) and statistical information gained on national level.
in addition,fiuiure potentials - the
additional reaii'able mid-term potentials
up to 2020 -
were assessed taking into account the country-specific situation as well as overall
real isation constraints.
We show in the following the sector specific generation potentials of the different RES
technologies in the sectors electricity, heat and transport. As the biomass potential is
endogenously allocated to the sector by the model, it can not be allocated to the sectors at
this stage. At the end of this
section
we give an overview of the lrimary hiotnass
Poteiltials used in this analysis.
RES-E potentials
Table 6 provides an overview of tue already achieved potential
(at the
end of 2004) and the
additional i-ca] isable mid-teini potential (up to 2020) for differeal RES-E options available
in EU countries separated in EU-IS and EU-] 0. In total EU-I 5 the already achieved
potential for RES-E equals 441 TW]i, wheteas the additional mid-term potential (excluding
biomass options / biogas solid biomass and biowastci amounts
to
696 TWh. Corresponding
figures for the EU-JO are I 89 TWh for the achieved potential and 37.3 TWIt for the
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0015.png
additional
mid-term potential (excluding biomass options
/
biogas solid biomass
and
biowaste).
Table 6 Overview on electricity generation potentials for RES-E in the EU
AT BE DX Fl FR DE CR IE IT LU NL PT ES SE UK EUI5
Electricitygeneration
potentials(EU15)
I
f5
2
-
a
Z
.8
a
ileedotentialk2004
l3iogas OWli 218 121 238 6067735115 2 115 1244 7 0
12247
_JQ Jfl
(Solid)
13ioniss
OWl: 2440 314 1228 9134 1764 2972 0 0 522 0 1036 1234 '1442 3578 1613 30748
Biowaslo OWl: 43
316 732
225 2442 2027
23 t351
0 0
518
651
1660
468 003
11464
rLjlelcclrit OWh 7 0 0 0 00 0 55490 0
W5
0 0 0 5682
lIvdro1arscaIe OWh 33587 137 0 p803 60220 576 3280 703 35565 0 W697 29681 68856 4562 213374
Ilydro small-scale OWl: 4138 192 31 1178 6219 7361 163 06 8467 100 1 697 '1710 3224
515
37369
Pliotovollaics GWh
5
1 I 0 8 621 1 0 17 8 32 34 0
5
758
Solar thermal electricity OWl 1) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 9 0 0 0 0
Tidc& Wave _________ OWl: 0
0
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 o 0 0 0 0 6
Wind onshore GWh 1273 95 5943 1711 973 29516 1023 793 2649 73 2383 1171 12592 980 2027 67695
Wind offshore OWh 0 0 14.12 0 0 0 11 80 0 0
53 0 0 21
290 1870
RES-E TOTAL GWI 41921 275
9631
24278 12924 53370 4630 1808 55685 231 5287 14422 58786 77273 14637 441205
Additional resIisable !tial (up to 2020)
Geo1llcrlt1aIrici1 OWl U 00 0 152 0 2210 22 00 159 95 0 0 2399
Ihydro large-scale OWl: 59 4 0 Hl0 5 2974135695 10527
0 0 3353
15110 W63 L70
39312
Hydro small-scale (iWli 5302 98
0494
4723 2228 208 109 7I 0 81076 2630 07 193
20953
Photovoltaics OWI: 972 531 497 000 5902 4840 1043 310 3691 5 1173 955 5101 1287 4321 31220
Solar thernial electricity OWL: 0 0
-_Q __9 .2
-
0 0 29085
-
__Q no j2Q_
Tide & Wave OWl: 0 ISO 25112 545 13152 7725 4007 3930 3220 0 1026 7404 13229 3006 58295 119377
Wind nshorc OWl: 70% 4123 2756 7679 55436 23803 7814 959 25977 147 3169 5636 20707 8932 26439 198479
Wind offshore
OWli 0 048 9181 4105 39970
76342 2635 3502 2396 0 19789 6599 144.14 3544
66308
253611
OtES-E TOTAL (cxci. flM) OWli 11447 8603 15216 15534 011111 110412 19917 9906 57428 152 25164 27835 82531 29743 156785 695790
RES-E
- CV Cl EE [ILl LA LI
_
.e
.
.
MT Pt, 5K 51 EUIO lOG 110
Jtleetrtcitygeneration
potentials (EUIQ)
I
.2
-
Achieved potential
(2004)
Biomis
(Sohid hiioinass
lOiivSlC
glicrmal cIecriciIy
Flydro large-scale
Hvdr small-scale
Photovoilaics
Sohrllicrnialclcclricity -
TV/I:
TWh
TW1:
TWI:
TV/I:
L'Wh
Tide & Wave
Wind onhre
Wind olTslioic
________
TWh
TW6
TW
TWI,
RES-ETOTAL
mvi
Geothermal
clccLi_
Additional realisable potential
TV/li
h1>1:jr e-sealc
TWl:
TWa
llvilro_small-scale
TV/I:
PhtovoItnics
________
Solar thermal elccIrieii
Tide & Wave
WilidoilSliorc
:
1WI:
2084
6312
362
0
35
4
610
17
211
0
0
0
239
(127 4469
271
0
1158
8349
(up to 2020)
0
0
O
'1
610
7
214
739
627
271
158
0
'1489
0
5309
I'll
2
57
0
_____________________________
__
_
____________________________
401 2213
481
736
999
15670 135 5197
702
55
7373
3431 U277 3419
1199
32 23310
3303
008
62053 743 15426
117
171
29
25
112
1614
254
3113
3706 226
926
0
0
0
1090
672
0
224
0
45 Jj
4582
7067 SOt
78
156
0
39
109
500
767
3511
2622 401
673
300
115
24
9
20
29
91
33
1051 158
275
0
1)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0 (1
1223
0
528
303
60
0
3366 802
1112
(1
510
1246 1190 1232 1257
557
110
8482
299
19491 734 6693
0
0
ill
48
301
211
2451
0
3693 133
151
1970
2839 2473 2923
390 3358
1562 5271
31292
275 35116
___________
_________
o
_________
0
0
39
20
_
o
1091)
72
IS
0
1190
0
2173
1176
158
21
231
09
29
.
o
0
0
9
60
110
211
390
o
o
5011
91
-
o
82
356
33
1)
299
0
5271
o
20
45
767
500
_9
1223
1216
311
2839
528
1232
301
2923
Q
201
257
148
910
1112
6.162
2-151
13358
0
557
0
1562
Wind offshore
EES-E TOTAL{xcI. ISM)
iWh
TV/h
TWI:
7067801
5197
21122 '101
673
1651 15$
375
0
0 0
3366 202
510
19491 131 0693
3693
'133
151
37292
84
13596
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0016.png
RES-H potentials
Table 7 shows the achieved potential in 2004 and the additional RES heat generation
potentials (excluding biornass) for 2020 at member state Level (EU-15 and EU-b &
Bulgaria, Romania. The already achieved potential in 2004 amounts to 40.9 Mtoe for the
EU-I
5
and 8.4 Mtoe for the EU-l0; whereas the additional potential until 2020 totals 63
Mtoe for the EU-IS and 7 Mtoe for the EU-I 0 (excluding biomass).
Table 7: Overview on heat generation potentials for RES-H in the EU
AT lIE DiC FE FR L)E OR JE IT UI NL PT ES
RES-H
-
I-Teat
.5
generation
.
SE
'
UI( EUI5
-
-
.
'.
lotential(EUI5)
I
s
.
________
-
a
z
e
-_________________________
Achieved potential
(20041
___________________ _________
2.118 461 915 5319 9442 5142 920 191 2393 1$ 382
2480
3453 5085 703 39339
___________________________
81cc
Go0icrmI hcal (CIW&
dO.) kcc 9
3 0 113 7 13 1
160
0 0 9 8 23 2 376
1lcl pcnps 1008 85 7 46 77 86 0 0 0 0 0 263 1 625
Selorcollcclors kcoc 87 2 10 0 29 221 128 0 18 0 IS 6
54 6
25 600
RES-H TOTAL 81cc 2608 492 940 5306 9660 5469 061 192 2592 6 428 2494 3515 5377 731 40940
Additional
realisable potential
(up
to
2020) ______________________________________
Gcciltcriccccl hcai (CI1P&d.l.)
-
_to.o. ...J.
c
0
.........j!!T. __......j
_.1
... ...........^!.
0
_..
s ___j
9
2189
I4cnI
JiLiIIp
2222
05
l
Th
27683
SoIarcolIccIrs 81cc 576 826 673 662 5882 6403 764 310 0033 37 1268 854 3323 803 4799 33214
RES-IL TOTAL 8(00 1327 2005 1486 1152 10165 4246 1270 622 11222 102 2515 1144 4668 1510 9653 63087
CV CZ. EE 8181 L.A Li' MT FE. SX
RES-H-Heatgencration , .
SI
EVID PG RO
potential(EUIO) ,i1I.
-
I
576
0
2
=
0
ci
_AcliievcdyoteiitiQfl
81cc
(ico9icruciI Ocal (CO1P & clii.)
]1ct cincpo
Sc1arcoIlcors
81cc
ktec
8cc
8108
______
______________
____
____________________________
___
0
0
0
793
2
7
492
0
7
564
89
055
0
0
0
1Q55
2865
6
14
=
3658
265
72
0
430
IS
0
8033
285
27
709
0
0
3647
0
0
1
3050
0
61
9
755
20
2
0
2
=
= = =
61
1
1
3
RES-IL
TOTAL.
20
603
.194
578
39
163
164
367
1
2
=
449
339
2
33
=
0383
376
3283
33.19
7008
711
Gccicnlic1lIC141411.7
Sclcrcolicctoi
Ik
0
23
0
59
51)
118
46
446
129
521
61
W3
95
107
1)
U6
L4
1771
3601
50
216
507
107.
66
(26
316
RIO
121
361
599
1861
H192
1185
2376
Q
k1o
81cc
65
52
'110
883
2
14
16
RES-FI 'rOTAL
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0017.png
RES-T potentials
Table
8 provides an overview on the achieved biofuel potentials on countiy-leveL The
achieved RES potentials for 2004 showed 1930 ktoe for the EU15, and 171 ktoe for the
EU-l0.
Table 8
Overview on biofuel potentials (RES-T) in the EU
AT BE
DK
.
F
FR
DE
GR IE IT LU
NL
PT
ES
SE UK
EU 15
RES-T-Biofuelpotential
(EUI5)
Achievcl potential (20041
I3iofLjeI
kwo 51 0
S
L.
E
0
-J
I
z
a.
0 41
EULO
0) '
62
CY
CZ
2
362
975
0 0
285
0
7
37 5
L930
EE
nU
S
LA tT MT PL
5K SI
.
PG RO
RES-T- Biofuel potential
(EUIO)
C)
Athivepotentialjul04i ____________________________________________
mofuel koc 0 0 I 5 6 0 24 23 0 171 0 0
Primary biomass potentials
A crucial
input to
the model is given
by
the primary potentials olsolid biomass. These
were determined in this project based on the analysis of the following sectors:
Agricultural l)rod1cts
Agricultural residues
Forestry products
e
Forestry residues
Biodegradable waste
Forestry impOrtS
In the following 1'ab1e 9 gives an overview on the potentials used in this Project.
Thereby for agricultural products it was assumed that I
5%
of the arabic land will he used
for energy crops. For the total area attributed to energy crops a pre-allocation to the
individual crops was done as indicated in the table. This implies already a cerlain
predetermination of the future conversion lechnologies (e.g. lOt versus generation
hiofuels).
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0018.png
Table 9 Overview on primary biomass potentials in the EU
Potentials (in terms of
orimarv enerov)
2010
205
Mto
ItU
API
-
rape & sunflower
4.6
4.7
3.4
AP.2 maize
wheat
(Oom)
143 145 02
AP3 -maize wheat (whole plant)
0.0
11.1
22.2
AP4 SRC willpw
13
36
58
AP5-miscanthus
1.3
3.3
5.2
AP6 swi(ch grass
18
65 11 2
AP7
-
sweet sorghum
1.4
4.0
2.7
ARI straw
21 6
227
239
AR2
- other
agricultural residues
2.3
2.4
2.6
FP1 forestry products (cfirreit use (wood chips log Wood))
27 9
279 279
FP2 -forestry products (complementary fellings (moderate))
8.2
8.7
9.1
12,4 .. .13.0
(exphiv))..'
137
FRI
-
black liquor
14.5
13.6
15.2
FR2 forestry residues (current use)
143
14 3
14 3
FR3 -forestry residues (additional)
2.3
26
2.5
Fl4 demolition Wood industrial residue&
,
71
74
87
.
FR5 -addilionat wood processing residues (sawmill, bark)
4.8
5.0
5.3
:25
.-39
8W1
-
biodegradable fraction of municipal vaste
11.8
13.2
14.8
Agricultural products
51.0
46.3
Agricultural residues
23.9
25.2
26.5
46 6
L
5
5
42.0
Forestry residues
43.4
44.9
-
Biodegradablewaste
132
118
148
rorestry imports 2 5 3 1 39
Solid biomass
.
TOTAL
153.5
180.7
201.8
-
Solid biornass Primary potentials &
corresponding fuel cost
-
2005
Mth
2020
1o
2.2
0
33.3
1
7.1
15 9
5.3
252
2.7
279
9.6
.
16.0
143
2.7
78
5.6
--
16.7
75.8
27.9
52 0
46.4
167
4.8
223.8
A. 6.Assessment of & overview on the economic data
for RES
Assessment of economic data for RES'-E & RES-H
(electricity and grid-connected heat sector)
The assessment of the economic parameter and accompanying technical specifications of
for the various RES-E technologies comprises a COmprCbCUSiVC lilot-ature survey and an
expert consultation. With respect to existing plant, representing the already achieved
poteutia] at the end of 2001, also project specific inforniation is taken into account.
References of major relevance are discussed below.
A set of studies is listed which provide a comprehensive survey on RES-E technologies,
t]iereby including detailed economic and Eechtiical data with respect to most common
technologies. Namely these are, listed in chronological order: (DTI/ETSU, 1999)
(DLR/WI/ZSW/IWR/Forum, 1999), (Neubarth et al., 2002), (Haas et al., 2001), (Resch
et al., 2001), (Nowak et at., 2002), (Kaltschmitt et at., 2003), (BMU, 2004).
References with a focus on selected technologies are listed in the following by
RBS-E category:
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0019.png
• l3iogas and Biomass: (Fischer et aL, 2002), (Enquete, 2002), (EUBIONET, 2003)
• Geothermal energy: (EMU, 2002)
• Hydropower: (Lorenzoni, 2001)
• Photovoltaics: (Aiserna, 2003), (Schètffer et aL, 2004)
Solar thermal electricity: (Quaschning, Ortrnann , 2003)
• Wind energy: (Greenpeace, 2001), (Neii et aL, 2003), (BTM, 1999-2003),
(Beurskens, Noord, 2003)
• Tidal and wave energy: (Thorpe, 1999), (DTJ/ETSU, 2001), (Michael, 2003)
Assessment of economic data for RES-l-I (non grid)
The assessment of the economic parameter and accompanying technical specifications of
for the various RES-H technologies comprises a comprehensive literature survey and an
expert consultation. in particular the following sources were consulted for the techno-
economic assessment:
Invert (2005)
Ja]rbuch Erneuerbare Energien (2004)
I3STIF (2003)
Kaltschmitt et al. (2003)
DLRIWJ/ZSW/IWR/Forunr (1999)
BMU(2004)
o
o
Assessment of economic data for
RES-T
(Iio fuels)
The assessment for potential and cost figures foi' biofliels was based on a comprehensive
literature review and experts conversations among the biofüels industry members in
Europe. For the agricultural and biofuels techno-economic assessment following sources
were used and consulted:
CONCAWE (2003), Well-to-wheeF analysis of future automotive fuels and powertrains
in the European Context, Well Tank Report, Brussels, 2003. Available at:
http://ies.j rc.cec.eu. mt/Down load/eh
Energy Rcsearch Centre of the Netherlands ECN (2003). An overview of hiofuel
technologies, markets arid policies in Europe 2003, Available at:
hftp://www.ecn.rul/docs/library/reportf2003/c03008.pdf
ESTO, IPTS, (2003). Trends in vehicle and fuel technologies: Scenarios for Future
Trends" Ed. Luc Pelknians (VITO), Panayotis Christidis, Jgnacio Hidalgo, Antonio
Soria. Report EUR 20748 EN, 2004. Available at;
bttp:/Iwww.jic.cs
EST JPTS, (2003). Biofuel lroduction potential of EU-candidate countries - Final
Report, EUR 20835, 2003, Available at:
littp://www.jrc.es/home/publications/publication.cfm?pub= 11 20;
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0020.png
European Commission, DO Energy and Transport (2003), European Energy and
Transport Trends to 2030, Januay 2003 Available at
http://europa.eu. int/comin/dgs/energy_ti'ansportffigurestti'ends2O3 0/index_en.htin
European Commission (2003), Directive 2003/30/EC of the European Parliament and the
Council of 8 May 2003 on the promotion of the use of biofuels and other renewable
fuels for transport (OJ
L
123, 17.5.2003, p.42)
European Commission (2003) Directive 2003/96/BC of the Council oi27 October 2003
restructuring the Community framework for the taxation of energy products and
electricity (OJ L 283, 31.10.2003, p.51)
European Commission (2001), Green Paper towards a European strategy for the security
of energy supply. Available at http:/(europa.eu. mt/comm/energy transport/doe-
principa!/pubfinalen. pdf
European Commission (2001). White Paper: European Transport Policy 2010: Time to
Decide. http://europa.cu.int/comm/energytransport/library/!btextecom,leten.pdf
European Commission, DG Energy and Transport (2004). Promoting Biofuels in Europe:
Securing a cleaner future for transport. Available at
Energy scientific and technological indicators and references (2005), DO for Research
and Sustainable Energy Systems, EUR 21 611. ISBN: 92-894-91 69-8
Friedrich S. (2004), A World wide review of the conimercial production of Biodiesel - A
technological, economic and ecological investigation based on case studies, Band 41,
Institut fuer Technologie und Nachhaltiges Produktmanagement, Vienna 2004.
I-Iamelinck, C. (2004), Outlook for advanced biofuels, PhD 1)issertation Juiie 2004,
Utrecht University, Department of Science, Technology and Society. Netherlands.
ISBN: 90-393-3691-1
Henke, J., Kiepper, G., Schmitz, N. (2004): Tax Exemption for Biofuels in Germany: Is
B io-Ethanol Really an Option for Climate Policy? Kid Institute of Workl Economics
2004.
International Energy Agency lEA (2004). Biofuels for Transport. An international
perspective. Paris, France, April 2004. ISBN 92-64-0151 2-4.
lEA, CADETT, (1998), Mini-review of Energy
from
Crops and Crops Residues. UK,
January, 1998.
IPTS, (2002). Techno-economic analysis of Bio-diesel production in the EU: a short
sunimary for decision-makers, EUR 20279, 2002. Available at
hap://www.jrc.cs/honie/publications/publication.cfin?pub=990
IP'l'S, (2002). Techno-economnic analysis of I3io-alcohol
produetioii iii
the EU: a short
summary for decision-makers, EUR 20280, 2002
http:/fwww.rc.es/homc/pubJications/publication.cfm?pub=99 I
jirs, (2003). Biofuel production potemtial of EU-candidate counti'ies -• Addendum
to
the
Final Report, EUR 20836, 2003. Available at
http://www.ji'c.es/liome/publ ications/pubi icatiou.cfirm? Pu b 11 21
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0021.png
IPTS, (2004).The introduction of
alternative
fuels in the European transport sector:
Techno-economic barriers and perspectives - Extended summary for policy makers,
JPTS, Ed. Soria Antonio, et al.
Kaltschmitt, M., I-Iartmann, H. (2001). Energie aus Biomasse, Grundlagen, Techniken
mid Verfahren (In German). Springer Verlag 2001, ISBN:
3-54-64853-4.
Ryan, L.; Convery, F.;
Ferreira,
S.: Stimulating the use
of biofuels in the
European
Union: Implications for climate change policy. Working Paper, University College
Dublin, 2004.
Sustainable Energy fretand (SEt) (2004), Liquid Biofuel Strategy for Ireland study
prepared by Hameliuck Carlo; Van den Broek, Richard; Toro, Felipe; Ragwitz,
Mario; Rice, Bernard. Available at:
http://europa.eu. int/comm/energy/res/legislation/doc/biofuels/rneniber_statesl2004li
quid strategy study ireland.pdf
Toro, F. (2004). Techno-Economic Assessment of l3iofueJ Production in the European
Union. Master Thesis, Kailsruhe, TU Preiberg, 2004,
Wyman, Charles E., Handbook on Bioethanol: Production and Utilization. Applied
Energy Technology Series, Taylor & Francis 1998, ISBN: 1-56032-553-4.
Economic data for RES-E
Table 10 gives an overview economic parameter and accompanying technical
specifications on technological level by RES-E sub-category, referring to
new plant
of
the database in accordance with the
additional realisable mid-term
polenlial.
In case of
(large- arid small-scale) hydropower and wind onshore non-harmortised cost settings are
applied, i.e. a country-specific9 differentiation of investment- and where suitable also
O&M-costs is trnclei.taken, whilst for all other RES options harmonised cost settings are
applied. In the latter ease expressed ranges of the economic and technical parameter
result low different plant sizes (small- to large-scale) and / or applied conversion
technologies. Please note that nfl data - i.e. investment-, O&M-costs and efficiencies -
refer to the default start year' of the simulations, i.e. 2005, and are expressed in
' Especially in case of hydropower the range of investment costs differs largely between and
within the countries. These capital costs are site-specific, depending on the plant-size and
geographic conditions as well as on additional (country-specific) efforts (acceptance barrier,
planning process, etc.). The applied country-specific settings are based err (Lorenzoni, 2001).
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0022.png
Table 10 Overview on econornic-& technical-specifications for new RES-E plant
RES-E sub-
category
Plant specification
Agricultural biagas plant
Agricultural biogas pt -
CHP
Landfill gas plant
Landfill gas plant - CI-IP
Sewage gas plant
Sewage gas plant -CI-IP
Biomass plant -
CaShing
Biomass plant
-
CHP
-
Cofiring
-
CHP
Waste incineration plant
Waste incineration plant
-
CHP
Geothermalpowerplant
Investment
costs
L€IkW]
O&M
(€1
(iW.'yr.)]
Efficiency
(electricity)
IJ
0.28- 0.34
0.27
-
0.33
0.32-
o.s
0.31
-
0.35
0.28- 0.32
0.28- 0.3
0.26- 0.3
0.37
0.22
-
0.27
0.2
0.18-0.22
0.14-0.16
0.11 -0.14
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
.
Efficiency
(heat)
(1]
-
Ufelime
(average)
[years)
25
Typical
plant size
[MWOI]
2550
-
4290 115- 140
2760- 4500 120- '145
50- 80
55 -85
115- 165
125- 175
75
-
135
550
60
2600-4230 80- 165
550
60
4300 -5820 90-165
1260- 1840
1430- 1990
2300 -3400
2400- 3550
2225- 2530
4600-6130 100-185
2000-3500 100-170
_______
0l
-
0.5
0.1
-
0.5
0.75-8
0,55
-
0.59
-
25
25
25
25
25
30
30
30
30
30
30
30
50
50
50
50
50
50
50
50
25
30
25
25
Biogas
0.5- 0.54
-
0.54- 0.58
-
-
0.75- 8
0.1
-
0.6
0.1
-
0.6
1 -25
-
-________
Bi omass
-
0.63-0.66
0.6
-
0.64-0.66
-
1 -25
-
2-50
2-50
5-50
250
75
20
-
-
Biowaste
Geothermal
electricity
Hydro large-
scale
-. -______________
Hydra small-
scale
Photovoltaics
Solar thermal
electricity
Large-scale unit
850- 3650
1125-4875
Medium-scale unit
Small-scale unit - 1450 -5950
600- 3600
Upgrading
Large-scale unit
800- 1600
1275- 5025
Medium-scale unit
Small-scale unit
1560 -6050
Upgrading
900-3700
PV plant
.
5080- 5930
Large-scale solar thermal
plant
35
35
35
35
40
40
40
40
38 -47
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
______
9.5
2
0.25
-
0.005
-
0.05
2-50
0.5
1
2
0.5
2880-4465 163- 228 0.33- 0.38 -
44
-
-
Tidal (stream) power plant 2670
- shoreline
Tidal energy power plant
_______ _______ ________
_________
Tidal (stream) power plant
3025
- offshore
53
44
-
-
25
25
----.----- -----.--.
-
-
wave power plant:
shoreline
2135
Wave energy wave power plant- 2315 49 - - 25
nearshore
wave power plant-
-
25 2
2850
53
-
Wind onshore Wind power plant
wind power plant -
wind power plant -
offshore: 5.30km
-------
wind power plait -
offshore: 30... 50km
wind power plant -
offshore: 0kim..
890- 1100
1590
1770
33-40
-
-
25 2
25 5
')
-
-
-
-
Wind offshore
1930
2070
54
-
-
2
5
-
-
25 5
_________ _____________
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0023.png
Default ranges for fuel costs with respect to the various fractions of biomass are depicted
in Table I I. These country-specific prices are mai iily based on (EUBIONET, 2003-
2005).. For biowaste as default a negative price of-4€/MWh was used, representing a
revenue for the power producer, i.e. a 'gate fee' for the waste treatment, Again, these
prices refer to start year of the simulation, i.e. 2005. Their future development is
intei'nahsed in the overall model - linked to fossil
fuel
prices as well as the available
additional potentials.
Table 11 Fuel price ranges for various fractions of solid biomass
in EU countries
ohdhic
as
-
Fuel ost
'c raros.(2O05l
:
32,3
26.6
29.3
274
27.1
179
:-
.-(èjused ir€pe M'4 ri]
rIQrC)y)
APi - rape & unfFo.ycr
:APrize, whbticorr] ,,
ARi rnaie, .'.hea (wio par)
AP-
CIow
I canlhus
APo itc
• •Manium
40.4
33.2
20.8
329
34.1
319
..
AP7 - sweet SOrghum
37 , 2
30.6
0.0
292
30 . 0
259
AiTtiaI;iuct Ttf1AL
AR1
-
straw
•'.'.
31.0
,,9
12.2
__________________________________________________
Argculturare&iduesI TOTAL
F1P 1 oresy prothcl,(currenVg c ee'd 'hip rog ioJ)
FP2- roreorry products (complerneniary feIFi-rnoderae)
3rPa •1cre1r piod rf' lernric&Ings(pehoIva)) •,.
h
01001'
40.9
40.9
: -.._40
...........
.
14.7
13
.
4
122
14 7
155
'12 2 .141 134
--
17 8
22
3
206
19.1
23.8
21
.
7
25.8
5.6
32.3
7.7
29.4
6.0
7 .0
139
I1'LiOr
.
-
-
-,
FR2-foreslrrcoidues(cj )
6.3
12
5
5.0
f-Ru c és,ry rsrdc.., (additrc'ialj
FR4 - demolilion wood, indusie'I ron. lies
rncess1ng re.iduLs (.owmi1I bai'k)
f
.:.
...
••.
,.•
8.6
17 1
.. - . . ..
-
.:
., .
BWI biodegradable fractional rirunicipal waste
6.8
63
86
;
.:..17.1.:'
.......
-3.8
5.9
69
.
-3.8
_______________________
.-:69-
-3.8
............
FR6-forestry imports from abrord 16.0 16.8 16.8
of which domestic biomass - -3.8 40.9 16.4
in order to give a better illustration of the currentt0 economic conditions of the various
RES-B options, electricity generation
coslst
depicted in the following figures. Their
calculation is based on the economic and technical specifications as depicted in
As usual, Costs refer' to the starting year for model simulations, i.e. 2005 and, hence, are
expressed in
"
Note that in the model Green-X the calculation of generation costs for the various generation
options is done by a rather complex mechanism as described further in this report, respectively,
internalized within the Overall set of modelling procedures. Thereby, band-specific data (e.g.
investment costs, efficiencies, full load-hours, etc.) is linkeci to general model parameters as
interest rate and depreciation time.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0024.png
Table 0, extended by missing parameters such as full load hours and fuel
prices
(in
case
of biornass), representing the broad range of resource-specific conditions among the EU-
15 countries.
The Grecii-X tool differentiates between
long-run marginal generation cost,t
that are
used for the simulation of investment decisions and
short-run marginal generation costs
which are the running costs that depict the operation decisions. These costs for the RES-
E category are presented in Figure 4 and Figure 5. Thereby, for the calculation of the
capital recovery factor two different settings are applied with respect to the payback
time:t2 On the one hand, a default setting, i.e. a payback time of 15 years. is used for all
RES-E options - Figure 4 (left), and art the other hand, the pay back is set equal to the
technology-specific life time (right). The broad range of costs for several RES-E
represents, on the one hand, resource-specific conditions as are relevant e.g.
in
the case of
photovoltaics or wind cner', which appeat between and also within countries. On the
other hand, costs also depend on the technological options available - compare, e.g. co-
firing and small-scale CHP plants for hiornass (small scale CHP
is
contained in
the cost
band
IrSO]jd
hiomass' shown below).
w1douth0rc
Wod onth0o
Soa 1Icm octrcy
l'tl
, J
-.
WIt
0t15J10113
cost rat (I.RMG)
Wind
nnhoc,
E
Sonr Lhernlai
lcIricity
:
::..
:
.::
.:
I
flolcango(LaMC)
Ilyt0
m0H40C
.
Hyco kuQe.coe
BiOw0te
(Soid
0md0,
I
1
r
L
__TT._:TTTI
.
! 130
to
-
Pttt0vInlo
Hy&o
smoI!.CaIo
tydrolargo
Geostermor olearicily
8iowate
.
..
31Oi12G0CMW-P
......
-
-:
-
F
[.
:...
:.
... . _
SO2) OF0i0.t
.
(Sn1d) Biomass .çq
. ... . .. ...
lsottd) Siomos,
c-rit1ng
(3og:
..___
............
50 100 tSO 200
0
Costs 0f
esotriclty
(LRr.iC
.
Peytmclt
tintS:
Lifetinr,} [€AtWIt)
50 100 150 200
0
Co,js & cctiiy (L RMC
. Pnytntck
lint,: 15 yooroJ ((MWh
Figure 4 Long-run marginal generation costs (tar the year 2005) for various
RES-E options in IIJ countries -• based on a default payback time of
15 years (left) and by setting payback time equal to litetime
(right).
12
For both cases a default weighted average cost of capital (WACC) in size of 6.5% is used.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0025.png
Wo5horo
Tide&Wo
SoFr thorml ILriLy
1-fy*Q smafl.so
f-Iyfro1a.soI-3
Gao1hrmai eIcrc:y
I
rcørnof5RMCJ
1.
•:
(So1i)
8iornao -
{SoId} Bomass o.lirir.j
I
0
50 75 1CO 125
25
Cof of eFocricity SRMC} 5JMWhJ
Figure 5 Short-run margina' generation costs (for the year 2002) for various
RES-E options in EU countries
Figure
5
illustrates
short-run marginal genei-alion cosis'
by
RES-E
category. It is
evident that for most RES-E options these short-run generation costs, he. the
running
costs, are low compared to conventional power generation based on fossil fuels. One
exception in this context is biomass, where fuel costs and conversion efficiencies have a
huge impact on the resulting running costs.
The current situation, without consideration of expected technological change, may be
described as follows: RES-E options such as landfill and sewage gas, hiowaste,
geothermal electricity, (upgrading of) large-scale hydropower plant or co-firing of
biomass are characterised by from an economic point-of-view comparatively low cost
and by, in contrast, rather limited future potentials in most countries. Wind energy and in
some countries also small-scale hydropower or biomass combustion (in large-scale plant)
represent RES-E options with economic attractiveness accompanied by a high additional
realisable potential. A broad set of other RES-E technologies are less competitive at
present, compare e.g. agricultural biogas and hiomass - both if utilisecl in small-scale
plants, photovoltaics, solar thermal electricity, tidal energy or wave power although,
future pofentiaFs are in most cases huge.
Short-run marginal costs are of relevance for
the economic decision whether to operate an
existing plant or not.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0026.png
Economic data for RES-H
Table 12 gives an overview of economic parameters and accompanying technical
specifications on technological level for grid- (i.e. district heating) and non-grid heating
systems, referring to
new plant
of the database in accordance with the
additional
realirnble mid-term potential.
Table 12 Overview on ecoriomic-& technical-specifications for new RES-H
plant (grid & non-grid)
RES-FI
sub- Plant specification Investment O&M costs Efficiency Lifetime Typical plant
category costs (heat)'
(average}
size
[€/k\W,,12
Grid-connected heating systems
Large-scale unit
l€l(kWyr)]2
[11 lyears]
0.89
30 10
30 5
Sieat Me urn-scale unit
Small-scale unit
Geothermal Large-scale unit
- district
Medium-scale unit
heat
SmalI-scae unit
NOn-grid heatingystems
Biomass
non-grid
heat
Heat
pumps
Solar
thermal
h eal i ng &hot
water supply
-
350- 380
390- 420
475
-
550
800
1200-1500
2000 -2200 -
16- il
17-19
20 -22
50
55
57-60
0.87
0.85
0.9
0.88
0.87
30 0.5-I
30 10
30 5
30 0.5-1
20
20
20
20
20
0.015 - 0.04
0.02- 0.3
0.01 -0.25
log wood
wood chips
pellets
grOurldcoupled
255- 340
340- 610
390
-
530
900-1100
650- 1050
400 .4202
6-10
6- 10
6-10
0.75- 0.85*
0.78- 0.85*
0.85- 09
341
35451
-
-
5.5-7.5
10.5-Ia
0.015-0.03
0.015-0.03
earthwater
Large-scale unit
Medium-scale unit
Small-scale unit
5- 7
7.92
540- 5602
--
_______________________________
13-
900
-
9302
20
100-200
50
-
20
____________________ _______________
-
20
5-10
Remarks: In case of heat pumps we specify under the terminology "efficiency (haet)" the
seasonal performance factor-
i.e. the Output in terms of produced heat per unit of electricity input
2
In case of solar thermal heating & hot water supply we specify under the investment Ond O&M cost per unit of
m2
collector surface (instead of kW). Accordingly, expressed figures with regard to plant sizes are also
expressed in m2 instead of MW).
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0027.png
Economic data for RES-T (blo fuels)
Table 13 gives an overview economic parameter and accompanying technical
specifications on technological level for some selected RES-T plant, referring to
new
plant
of the database. Please note that all data i.e. investment-, O&M-costs and
efficiencies - refer to the default start year of the simulations, i.e. 2005, and are expressed
LII
€2005.
Table 13 Overview on economic-& technical-specifications for new RES-T
plant
RES-T sub-
category
Fuel input
Investment
COStS
Efficiency
O&M costs (transport)
Efficiency
(electricity)
Lifetime
(average)
(years]
20
20
Typical
plant size
]
5-25
5-25
[€I(kWy
ea
(11
W
-
________
iodiesel plant rape and sunflower
0.66
210 -860
10 . 5 -45
(FAME)
seed
-
_________
___________________
_________
energy crops (i.e.
Bioelhanol
-
0
.
57-
sorghum and corn ftorn 640-2200
32-110
plant (EtOH)
0.65
maize, triticale. wL
- ___________
______
______
__________________
--_______________
-
Advanced
bicethanol
plant(EtOI-l+)
energy crops (i.e.
sorghum and whole
plantsofmaize,
triticale,_wheat)
__________
1130-
1510 1
57
.71
0,58
-
0,65 1
0.05-
0.12 '
20
5-25
BIL (from
gasifier)
energy crops (i.e.
SRC, miscanthus, red
canary graSs,
switchgrass, giant red),
selected waste
streams (e.g. straw)
___________________
750- 56001
38- 280'
0.36
-
0.02
0.43 1
0.09
1
-
20
50
-
750
Remarks: In case of Advanced biosthanol and BtL cost and performance data refer to 2010 - the
year of possible market entrance with regard to both novel technology options.
A
7.
CacuIation of the dynamic cost-resource curve
In general, in the model
Greeii-X,
dynamic effects will he considered covering the areas
e costs (and related performance parameters) for new plants
available / realisable potential foi' existing and new plants, respectively.
The dynamic adaptation of the costs (investment costs and opei'ation and maintenance
costs) will take place at the
end
of one simulated year, i.e. the investment costs for the
yearn will be determined at.
I:he
end of the year
n-h
'J] dynamic assessment of the potentLat will lake place at two different stages in the
mode I:
o The evaluation of the
ai'aiiabiepoenuial 0/existing
plants
for the year a
will be
made - similar to the cost adapt:ation - at the end of'tlie simulation run in the previous
year.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0028.png
For new
plants,
the assessment of the
maximal realiable potent/al for the year n
takes place after the creation of the static cost-resource curve for the year a. The
reason why this step cannot also be carried out at the end of the year a- 1 (as done for
all other dynamic assessment steps), is that not all required information for deriving
the assessment parameters is available at that time - i.e. as policy settings can be
changed year by year, actual settings for the year a must he used which, of course,
are on]y available after the simulation for the year n is started. In moie detail the
following inputs must be available:
-
Input database supply
o Input database - existing plants
o Input database new plants
Stakeholder behaviour
o Investor
o Society
Policy instruments
o Supply-side strategies
o Demand-side strategies
In
the following, the development of the dynamic cost-resource curves will be explained
in more detaii for existing and new plant separately.
Dynamic cost-resource curve existing plants
The following describes how to adapt the already achieved potential of existing
l)laIltS.
As mentioned before, in the actual model implementation this step takes place during the
creation of the 4input database existing plants' for the year
ii,
i.e. at the end of the year
ti-I. The results of the simulation of one year show - among others- which poteiitially
new plants have actually been implemented. Therefore the database of existing plants
must be extended by these plants, i.e. the database for existing plants Consists - after
carrying out this step - of data for all plants already installed before the year
n-I
plus
those plants which
were
built in the year n-I . However, this also means that old plants,
which are at the end oftheir lifespan in the year
ii, are
still inciudcd in the adapted
database. Hence, in a second step, a. lifespan assessirent must be carried out. All plamts
which have to be decommissioned in the year n have to be excluded from the 'input
database existing plants.
In
the database the lifespan of the plant (share) of each band of the techinoIogv wiH be
compai'ed with the construction year of the plant. If construction year plus technology-
specific defined lifespan is smaller than year a, the plant will be decommissioned. This
means l:his potential will be subtracted from the available potential of existing planls in
the year n.' This l)1ocedure is schematically depicted in Figure 6.
"
Note: costs for replacing old plants with new ones
is
cheaper and acceptance is
hgher
compared to the construction of totally new plants at new locations. Therefore, the potential
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0029.png
-
-
-.
-
• .-Achieved potential
of
technologix nat
the
of yearn4
EndrII unyrnoftho
Irceyx
•flffl4
.+
.•
.
-
Achieved potential of technology x available ri
yearn
-..------t cQyrn (6Ml
fn),flji$b
.•
.
Figure Schematic plot of the development of dynamic cost-resource curves
for existing plant for the year n (mci, extension for new plant of the
yeoi- n-i and lifespan assessment of existing plants) (example for
the electricity sector only)
Note: these steps will be carried out at the end of the simulation for year n -
Dynamic ccstresource curve
new
plants
The methodology to derive a dynamic cost-resource
curve
for the year
n
for potentially
flew p]ant is mote complex titan it is for existing plants, because - as already tndrcatcd in
previous sections - this dynamic cost-resource curve for a certain year must he developed
from the (static) cost-resource curve related to the additional mid-term potential.
removed must be adequately considered in the dynamic parameter assessment in the following
years.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0030.png
Why is it necessary to start with the additional mid-term potential and derive the animal
potential backwards in time from 2020 to year a ('top down') instead of assessing the
additional potential for the next year directly by taking into consideration various
available barriers and obstacles for the next year ('bottom up')? The motivation is given
by practical reasons, namely,
data with respect to the additional mid-term potential are available for various
technoJogies, e.g. from projects like SAFIRE, BlGreen, etc. Therefore, compatibility
with other studies is given and, hence, correction and adaptation are easily feasible,
the potential for the yearn depends on parameters (e.g. policy strategies) which will
be set in the simulation for year n in year n and, hence, are not available as input
parameters for the simulation process before the yearn.
Nevertheless, in many cases, the results of this 'top-down' approach will be accompanied
and compared with the 'bottom up' approach, i.e. deriving the additional potential for
yearn by starting from year n-I. With this 'two-fold' approach it is secured that the
iotential derived directly by the 'bottom up' approach (here the available potential is
given by the minimum barrier for the next year does not exceed the additional mid-term
potential determined by the 'top-down' approach and evaluated in many international
studies. Note, a depiction referring to the 'top down' approach is given in Figure 7.
CO iñQ2O• Dynamic pararheter assessment
Year
c4/
• .. . . . .. . - O1WthCtLiI
__
d..,
,) .'4
-,Ll
I
Cost curve additional potential
year n .
(€MWhiJ.
•:
..
1
LTc
.:
:
:
...
Figure 7 Schematic plot of the cost curve development for the year a and
technology x
Dynamic cost-resource curves for t1e year n
The overall cost-resource curve for the year n can be derived by horizontal addition of
the already achieved potential (existing plants) and the available additional potential
(new plants). This procedure is shown in Figure 8.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0031.png
In
general,
it
can be said that the generation costs of RES are higher than those of
conventional energy sources. Moreover, costs, as weU as achievable potentials, differ
widely among the specific technologies. The combination of the cost-resource curves for
potentially new and already achieved plants represents the output of the database
'dynamic cost-resource curv&,
Gpst lsting plants.
year
n
,CoStôUñiêèdditiônl plànts
• :
year
n
•..•.
-_....
/
.•
.
pIsI4
-
-,
.. ... .
• - ... •:. .
.....
.
C
f.srâ •àdd$tiô1al
plantsfyear n
Is
LTMC
ElM
WhJ
eiecyOuu,rIur.(a'Ms
Figure
8 Combirialion of cost-resource curves for already achieved and
additional potential for the year n and technology x (shown for
etectricfty sector only)
Summing up, the future penetration ofa certain technology depends on how ii: prevails
over two categories of obstacles:
Economic barriers - they are reflected by the net generation costs, i.e. inclusive
poi icy strategies (if applicable).
Other (non-economic) barriers as described above they restrict the available
potential of
RES
generation in year n
Penetration of a technology will only take place if both categories of barriers can be
overcome. So, on the one hand, it does not help to support a certain technology via a
quota obligation, a guaranteed feed-in tariff or a tender scheme without preparing the
framework conditions to overcome the other existing barriers, e.g. increasing the social
acceptance by infonnation campaigns. or decreasing administrative burdens for
commissioning new plants, etc.. In other words, low (net) generation costs but high non-
economic barriers still result in less additional penetration. On the other hand, providing
a good environment at acim inisti-ative, social, industria' and technical levels (i.e.
admitting a huge l)ctcflflal) without economic incentives does not increase the future
Ienetration rate of a certain technology. For instance, a high potential of electricity
generation but high generation costs also results in
a
low market share.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0032.png
A 8 Data for the dynamic aspects
A dynamic cost-resource curve
represents a tool to provide the Linkage between the
formal description of costs and potentials by means
of static cost-resource curves
(as
presented in the previous sections of this chapter) and the dynamic cost assessment as
e.g. done by application of
experience curves
as well as the implication of dynamic
restrictions in accordance with
technology dTusion.
Accordingly, data referring to these dynamic aspects will be presented in the following.
First, data with respect to the dynamic Cost (and performance parameter) assessment is
outlined, followed by a description of the specifications for dynamic (non-economic)
barriers.
Data for the dynamic cost assessment
With respect to technological change, the following dynamic developments of the
electricity generation technologies are considered:
Investment costs
Operation & Maintenance costs
Improvement of the conversion efficiency and related performance parameter
For most RES-.E technologies the future development of investment cost is based on
technological
learning.
As learning is taking place on the international level the
deployment of a technology on the global level must be considered. For the model runs
global dcploynient consists of the following components:
Deployment within the EU 25 Member States is endogenously determined, i.e. is
derived within the model.
Expected developments in the 'Rest of the world' are based on forecasts as
presented in the lEA World Energy Outlook 2004
(lEA,
2004).
'
For the case that only a single Country
S
investigated, a detault forecast
would
he
tar<en as
reference for the RES-E deployment on E1J-25 level.
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0033.png
Table 14 Default settings with respect to the dynamic assessment of
investment costs for
RES-E
& RES-H technologies
RES category
BIOCAS
_________________
Applied approach
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBAL)
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBALI
EXPERT FORECAST
___________________
Assumptions
LR (LEARNING RATE)
=
10-12.5%
___________________________________
LR
=
10-12.5% AS DEFAULT, COST DECREASE OF
1.5%/YEAR IN CASE OF CO-FIRiNG
COST DECREASE OF 1.5%/YEAR
________________________________________
BIOMASS ELECTRICITY
&
Clip
BEOMASS DISTRICT
HEATING
BIOMASS NON-GRID
_________________________
EXPERIENCE CURVE
LR =5-10% DEPENDING ON TECHNOLOGY
___________________________________________________
LR= 10%, EXPERT FORECAST UP TO 2012 IN CASE
OF NOVEL TECHNOLOGIES
__________
LR
=
8%
_________________
__________
(EU25)
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(EU2S)
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBAL)
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBAL)
EXPERT FORECAST
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBAL)
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBAL)
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(EU2S)
BIOFUEL FOR
TRANSPORT
GEOTHERMAL
ELECTRICITY
GEOTHERMAL
HEAT
_________
LR 5%
_________ ______________________
HYDROPOWER
PHOTOVOLTAICS
_______________
COST DECREASE OF
1.2%/YEAR
LR
=
20% UP
TO
2010, 12% AFTER 2010
___________________________________
LE
=
18%
UP
TO 2010, 12%
AFTER
2010
___________________________________
LR =5%
SOLAR THERMAL
ELECTRICITY
SOLAR
THERMAL
_______________________
TIDAL & WAVE
-___________________
WIND ON- & OFFSHORE
________________________________________________
EXPERT FORECAST
COST DECREASE 5%/YEAR
UP
TO 2010, 1%/YEAR
AFTER 2010
__________________
_
LII
=
9.5%
EXPERIENCE CURVE
(GLOBAL)
Default assumptions with respect to technological learning or the cost decrease,
respectively, as depicted in Table 1 4 are based on a literature survey and discussions at
eipert level, Major references are discussed below:
Various studies have recently ti-eated the aspects of technologica) learning
with
respect to
energy technologies. Iii a genera] manner, covering a broad set of(RES-E) technologies,
experience curves are discussed in (GrObler eta]., 1998), (Wene C. 0., 2000),
(McDonald, Schrattcnho]zer, 2001) and (BMU, 2004). A focus on photovoltaics is given
in (Alsenia, 2003) and (Schiffer eta]., 2004), whilst in case of wind energy (Neij et at.,
2003) provides the most comprehensive recent survey. With respect to the future cost
development of emerging new technologies like tidal and wave energy a stick to expert
lbrecasts giveil by (OXERA Environmental, 2001) SeemS prcfei'ab]e.''
The future development of biomass prices as relevant for electricity and heat
production based on biomass and biowaste is -- as default ' based on the following
' The currently implemented modelling approach ecconts solely learning on the commercial
market place, Efforts with respect to R&D, which do not result in additional deployment
measurab'e in terms of MW instal'ed, would otherwise neglected, but are of crucial relevance for
technologies in the early phase of deployment see (GrUbler et al, 1998).
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0034.png
settings: On average an increase of
0,5-1.5%
per year is projected, depending on fuel
categoly and country.
Data with respect to dynamic barriers
Within the model
Gi'eej,..X
dynamic barriers describe the impact of non-economic
deficits on the deployment of a certain RES, They represent the key element to derive the
dynamic potential for a certain year from the overall remaining additional realisable mid-
term potential (up to the year 2020) for a specific RES. Thereby, the impact of three
different types of several bai-riers can be investigated, e.g. technical, societal or
market & administrative constraints.
As defauli
technical
and
societal constraints are
considered only for onshore wind
energy. Thereby, the simplified percentage approach has been adopted. More precisely
the yearly realisable potential is restricted to a level of 50% of the remaining additional
mid-term
potential on band-level.
In contrast, the
most
important non-economic constraint, i.e. the combined indicator for
market & administrative barriers, is well applied to all RES-E categories in each
country. The application of this barrier results in a teclmology penetration following an
'S-curve' pattern - of course, only if financial incentives are set appropriate.
The required data in this respect is described below. Thereby, the following parameters
have to be defined:
Econometric factors A, B and C:
They predefine the possible increase of market deployment over time for a certain
technology on countiy-levcl. i.e. a high absolute value of A (e.g. 0.7) would allow a fast
market deployment (of course, if the harrier level bM is set high, too). In this context, the
technology-specific figures are derived from the in-depth investigation of the historical
development of RES-E in Europe imdertaken within the project
"FORRES 2020"
(see
(Ragwitz
Ct
aL, 2004)). Hence, the chosen figures refer to best conditions as observed for
several RES technologies in the past in European countries.
Barrier
level
This parameter defines the country-specific conditions - he. how far these conditions
differ from the technology-specific 'idea,l case (i.e. fi'om the as above explained
historical observed best conditions in a certain countly). Thereby, a value of 0 indicates a
Cvely high harrier', whilst a value of 1 refers to a 'vely low barrier', i.e. the ideal case'.
An illustration offlie clefhult setting is given in Figure 9, which depicts the ranges on
technology-level, referring to the electricity sector. These default settings refer to the
cuirCot situation of the various RES-E options in the investigated countries
as assessed
within the project
"FORRES 2020"
(sec (Ragwitz ci al., 2004)).
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0035.png
1'LOW 4,0
I,irr4r 35
.
..
-.
ra1ge
'1.:SI..!
IUGH 05
0.0
.9 E
,
..
...
gi
.
..
.
-.
.
..
..
-a
.2
-
,
>
.
.
U.
I-
Figure 9 Modelsettings of dynamic parameters: Country-specific ranges of
applied market
barrier level (bM)
by RESE technology
Lower boundary (minimum) for yearly realisable
market potential
A
constant minimum level of the yearly realisable market potential is considered for each
RES-E
category on country level. Otherwise - if a technology enters a new market - no
market potential would be available at the initial stage.
Similar to above, a depiction is given on countiy as well as on technology Level: Figure
10 indicates ranges on technologylevel, resulting from differing settings by country
(referring to the electricity sector). Again, default settings take into account i:he eulTdnt
conditions for the various RES-E options in each country.
900i
................................
0
...
.
.
...
0>. 700
........................................................
H
see
......................................................................................
1,
8004
............................................
-
o00
w
300
.
100
0
..................................................................................
.......................................... ..
.
-
.
-
. .,
I
.
H
.rzQr8
...................
J
...
..
......
..•.
.............
fl
Figur e 10:
II
Model-settings of dynamic parameters: Country-specific ranges
of applied minimum market potentials (/
Pn
mm)
by RlSF
te cli no logy
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0036.png
Annex Ib: Short characterisation of the model
GreenNet
The toolbox
GreenNet
developed by EEG, represents the core product of the overall
project GreenNet during its duration in the period 01/2003 to 12/2004.
The
GreenNet
model allows to simulate different scenarios, which enable a comparative
and quantitative analysis of strategies for an enhanced least-cost integration of RES-E
within the liberalised electricity sector both for all considered EU countries (I.e. initially
all EU]
5
countries and the new Member States Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and
Slovakia) as a whole as well as individual Member States for the period 2005 to 2020, It
is important to mention that the geographical coverage has been recently extended within
ongoing research activities'7 to the EU25 plus Bulgaria and Romania.
Similar to
Green-X,
the general modelling approach to describe both supply-side
electricity generation technologies and electricity demand reduction options is to derive
dynamic co3l-resource curves
for each generation and reduction option in the
investigated region. Dynamic deployment of RES-E is policy-driven where a similar
pathway can he set as for the electricity sector within the
Green-X
model.
Of special interest within this project are the following model features:
Cost of system operation and grid extension in case
of intermittent RES-E
Besides the policy settings, an additional feature is included in the overall simulation
model,
which is worth to mention:
The cost-allocation tool for system operation
and
I
or grid extension costs
in accrdancc with intermittent
RES-E.
Within the
toolbox GreenNet such costs can be
exemplarily determined for its
most
prominent
representati W rid power.
Besides a variety of settings to determine the overall calculation procecluie the user has
the possibility to determine the allocation of the accordingly calculated cost. In general,
they can either be applied to the consumer (society) ot' to the producer / investor. The
later setting allows getting aware ofa likely impact in terms of reduced wind
installations, etc. In addition, trade-offs between PolicY insti'uments and this cost-
allocation can be clearly expressed and determined.
An overview of the core elements oltlie Green
Wet
model is given in iigwe 11,
Within the follow-up project
GreenNet-E1J27
the extension
of the
geographical
coverage of the model to
all
10 new Member States, the candidate countries Bulgaria, Rornania
was recently undertaken - a luither expansion to include Croatia
as
well
as
Switzerland and
Norway is planned for the
near future. For
further information on these follow-up activities please
gi'eennet-europe.og.
Visit
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0037.png
ackqround dath base GreenNet
country-specific data
for suppiy-&clemand-slde options. for ohc instrumen fo RES-E
cO(baae'aar: 2005) & potentials (base year: 2020)
•i
0
- dmamlc parameter(cost development
(e.g.
Iaarning rates), -. p° •d ' y
200$t 020
r -
for general parameters:
non.linsncial
realization
barriers)
reference
electricity prices,
-
-
demand
lorecait
(2005 to 2020)
.
.
_______
______________________
POtICy instrumCnts Gancrat parameters bemnd reduction
(for RES E) (prlce & demand) otrons (DSM)
-------------------------------------------
Sensitivity tool for wind
energy:
Cests
for
jiid
extension
and
I
or
svf$tern operation
-
=
-
-
-
Selection
of cost-scenario (tow- moricrete- high)
-
Definition of cost socialization
(coneumer-pmducerj
:DeterflJon of
potentials, costs etch pricCs-.
doma rid srde
per sob secto
cost resource
.
--.T
curves
or.$'rJi)
eisubsector
+
demand side
:-
Feedback
year n+1
Feedback
ye5rn+1
Figure JJ-2
Figure ii. Overview on the core elements of the model GreenNef
The model
GrenNet
aims to deliver a broad set of results. All results can be provided
on a yearly basis on country-, EU- and / or tzchnology-levcl.
In more detail, mode] outputs can be categorized as follows:
o
General
Installed capacity [MW]
- Electricity generation {GWh]
- National electricity consumption [GWh]
- Wholesale market price electricity (yearly average prce) [€/MWh]
Market price Tradable Oreen Ceitificates [E/M Whj
-
PDF to HTML - Convert PDF files to HTML files
548808_0038.png
- Total e[ectdcity savings [GWIiJ
• Impact on producer or society
-
inciudin. e.g..
- Additiona' costs due to DSM strategy [ME,
€fMWh]
- Additional costs due to system operation [ME, €/MWh}
- Additional costs due to grid extension [ME, E/MWh]