Skatteudvalget 2015
KOM (2015) 0302
Offentligt
1537879_0001.png
EUROPEAN
COMMISSION
Brussels, 17.6.2015
SWD(2015) 121 final
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
Corporate Income Taxation in the European Union
Accompanying the document
Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council
on a Fair and Efficient Corporate Tax System in the European Union: 5 Key Areas for
Action
{COM(2015) 302 final}
EN
EN
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
Contents
1.
2.
3.
3.1.
3.1.1.
3.1.2.
3.1.3.
3.2.
3.2.1.
3.2.2.
3.2.3.
4.
I
NTRODUCTION
............................................................................................................ 3
C
ONSULTATION OF
I
NTERESTED
P
ARTIES
.................................................................. 6
T
AX
C
OMPETITION IN THE
E
UROPEAN
U
NION
........................................................... 7
T
HE
R
OOT OF THE
P
ROBLEM
: W
HERE ARE
P
ROFITS TAXED
? ......................................... 7
T
HE
B
ASIC
M
ECHANISM
................................................................................................ 7
T
HE
C
HALLENGES DUE TO
G
LOBALIZATION
.................................................................. 8
T
HE
T
AX
P
OLICY
R
EACTION
......................................................................................... 9
E
MPIRICAL
E
VIDENCE
................................................................................................. 15
D
EVELOPMENT OF
C
ORPORATE
I
NCOME TAXATION
.................................................... 15
M
OBILITY OF CAPITAL
................................................................................................. 20
P
ROFIT
S
HIFTING
......................................................................................................... 22
O
PTIONS
..................................................................................................................... 27
R
EFERENCES
............................................................................................................................ 29
A
NNEX
1: S
TYLIZED FACTS ABOUT THE
CIT
IN THE
E
UROPEAN
U
NION
1995-2015
A
NNEX
2: A
PPLICATION OF THE
C
OMMISSION
R
ECOMMENDATION ON AGGRESSIVE
T
AX
P
LANNING AND ON
M
EASURES TO
E
NCOURAGE
T
HIRD
C
OUNTRIES TO
A
PPLY
M
INIMUM
S
TANDARDS OF
G
OOD
G
OVERNANCE IN
T
AX
M
ATTERS
A
NNEX
3: P
LATFORM FOR
T
AX
G
OOD
G
OVERNANCE
A
NNEX
4: R
ELATIONS
EU
ACTIONS AND
BEPS
INITIATIVE
2
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0003.png
1.
I
NTRODUCTION
The taxation of multinational companies has come under scrutiny by tax
administrations, tax experts and the general public in recent years. More and more
evidence suggests that considerable amounts of corporate income from cross-border
activities can avoid taxation.
The business models of multinational companies have become
more complex, intra-group transactions have multiplied and multinationals' integrated value
chains make it difficult to determine where profits are created. Governments struggle to
determine within the current set of international tax rules which country should tax a
multinational's income.
Shifting income and capital across borders can lead to a loss of corporate income tax
revenues.
Many companies manipulate their internal prices and shift profits to low tax
jurisdictions. Digitalisation has made it easier for multinational companies to organise their
activities through off-shore financial centres, and to create sophisticated structures for tax
planning purposes. While differences in the statutory corporate income rates are one
important driver of profit shifting, also the effective tax rates companies face play a crucial
role since these rates also reflect preferential regimes and loopholes in national tax bases.
The existence of profit shifting practises is demonstrated in many academic and
empirical studies. Although the impact on total tax revenues is hard to measure, it might
be considerable.
1
Estimates for the United States find revenue losses of up to 25 per cent of
CIT revenue, while research by the IMF (2014) comprising 51 countries concludes that "the
(unweighted) average revenue loss is about 5 % of current CIT revenue – but almost 13 per
cent in non-OECD countries".
2
These observations have led to a more general debate on fairness, equity and efficiency
in taxation in the light of fiscal adjustment needs.
3
Base erosion has become even more
relevant in the context of rising concerns on fiscal sustainability following the financial crisis:
public debt levels have increased substantially in the EU from around 58% of GDP (EA 65%)
in 2007 to a forecasted value of 88% of GDP (EA 94%) in 2015. As a result of the crisis,
many governments cut expenditures while increasing taxes, notably on consumption, to
consolidate public budgets
4
. The use of several tax planning strategies by multinational
corporations has created a debate about their fair contribution to government budgets.
At the global level, the challenges related to the taxation of multinational companies
have increased the political pressure to strengthen the international rules of co-
operation in corporate tax matters.
5
Following the crisis and the increased revenue needs,
the OECD proposed an action plan against base erosion and profit shifting to reinforce the
current international tax rules and stabilize national tax bases. The OECD project focuses on
the interaction of different (national) tax rules and tries to detect and close loopholes in the
1
2
3
4
5
For a review of existing indicators and the associated challenges, see OECD (2015).
See IMF (2014) for further details. Zucman (2014) estimates the loss for the US at 20% of total CIT
revenue while the IMF (2014) quotes 25% as a maximum for the US.
According to Eurobarometer (2012) 88% of Europeans (EU-27) supported tighter rules on tax
avoidance and tax havens
http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb/eb78/eb78_cri_en.pdf.
For example, the average standard VAT rate has increased by 2 percentage points over the period 2007-
2014 in the EU. For a detailed description of tax reforms in Member States , see the Taxation Trends in
the European Union 2014 and the Report Tax Reforms in EU Member States 2014.
The OECD base erosion and profit shifting project (BEPS) was endorsed by the G20. See the G20
leader's declaration after their meeting in Los Cabos on 18-19 June 2012, p. 8, paragraph 48:
https://g20.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/12/G20_Leaders_Declaration_Final_Los_Cabos.pdf.
3
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0004.png
current setup.
6
The EU fully supports the on-going OECD work in this area and many of the
issues addressed by the OECD are of relevance also within the EU and are important for the
international competiveness of the EU enterprises as well.
7
Also, the EU plays an important
role in addressing these questions as it is one of the largest economic players in the world.
At the same time, the problems faced by the EU go beyond the issue of closing loopholes
in the existing international setup.
Tax avoidance and aggressive tax planning by
multinational companies distort price signals in the single market and thereby the allocation of
resources. Companies which use tax avoidance are more profitable and face lower capital
costs compared to domestic companies. This issue has to be addressed at the EU level to
ensure a level playing field for different types of companies.
While introducing unilateral anti-abuse measures by Member States might be a
valuable short term solution to fix the most pressing issues, the EU has to make sure that
an increase in national anti-abuse measures does not hamper the overarching goals of
the single market, the creation of a capital markets union and the overall attractiveness
of Europe at the global level.
Therefore, the issue has to be discussed from a wider
perspective in the EU. With its single market and a common currency in the Euro area, the EU
offers unique advantages to citizens and business. The economic integration within the EU
has increased welfare of citizens by lowering prices, increasing choices and removing
borders. Also, it has helped businesses to access larger markets, tap new sources of finance
and allocate their activities according to economic determinants rather than being limited by
national borders. This has led to an increased mobility of goods and services and production
factors within the EU which is most notably the case for capital. This mobility has improved
the allocation of resources. While the integration of markets has made progress, the taxation
of income from activities across the EU remains largely a national task. This can lead to
frictions in the single market due to tax obstacles. In addition, unilateral action to safeguard
national tax bases as currently discussed at the international level could in some cases
increase the number of obstacles if not properly coordinated.
The international debate has also renewed the interest in tax competition issues.
Some
people claim tax competition could be beneficial by creating more efficient corporate income
tax regimes and incentivize governments to offer attractive tax and public good bundles. Also,
some argue that limiting the power of governments to tax and thereby limiting excessive tax
burdens and excessive public spending is beneficial.
8
Critics argue that it is unclear why
competition for a mobile base in corporate income taxation should be justified by the idea of
'disciplining' overall government spending. They argue that democratic institutions like courts
of auditors and national parliaments are better placed to control governments' expenditures
than competition in one specific tax. Others state that the idea of benefit taxation seems at
odds with the reality that multinational companies are able to decrease their tax payments
irrespective of what tax and public good bundles being offered. This document does not
conclude which level of tax competition is desirable since this is largely a political
consideration. It notes however at a purely factual level that the recent developments have
changed perceptions of the costs tax competition might create for the common good at the
6
7
8
This debate is by no means new. These issues are discussed at the international level since more than a
century. An overview of the early development of the international system in the 1920s can be found in
Jogarajan (2013).
Annex 4 lists the EU initiative and their relation to the different actions in the OECD's base erosion and
profit shifting work.
See box 1 for an overview of the arguments and the literature on this idea.
4
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0005.png
national as well as at the EU level. These considerations include the more indirect effect the
tax avoidance of a few companies could have on the tax morale of all taxpayers.
9
While the EU has been active to find solutions to the issues of profit shifting, more
remains to be done.
Proposals for reforming corporate taxation have been discussed in
Europe since at least 1962 with the call from the Neumark Committee to gradually harmonize
tax systems in Europe. In the EU, the debate around corporate taxation began to emerge as
economic and political integration led to more cross-border activity. The primary focus was
on preventing problems which could hamper the development of the single market, such as
double taxation and tax discrimination. The Commission has highlighted the issues and
challenges of corporate tax systems in an economic union as well as their role for
competitiveness vis-à-vis third countries for many years starting with the 1962 Neumark
report followed by the 1970 van den Tempel report and the 1992 Ruding report.
10
In 1998 the
Code of Conduct for business taxation was established to limit harmful tax competition and
identify specific tax regimes considered harmful. In this context, also rules on the application
of the State Aid rules to measures relating to direct business taxation were published by the
Commission in 1998. In 2001, the Commission presented a Communication identifying
concrete steps to eliminate tax obstacles to cross-border trade in the EU. This was followed by
10 years of technical preparation, culminating in the Commission's 2011 proposal for a
Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB). More recently, the fight against tax
fraud and tax evasion moved to the centre of European efforts, being at the focus of the 2012
Action Plan against fraud which among others led to an amendment of the Parent Subsidiary
Directive to allow Member States the use of unilateral measures against profit participating
loans as well as to the establishment of the Platform for Tax Good Governance.
11
The
transparency package proposed in March 2015 contains a number of proposals to improve
transparency and information flows between tax administrations, notably on tax rulings. Some
of the policy options put forward to deal with profit shifting could also potentially address the
debt bias in corporate taxation stemming from the asymmetric treatment of debt and equity.
This issue has indeed become particularly relevant following the financial crisis because it
may lead to an excessive leverage and it may prevent the creation of a single integrated
European capital market.
12
While corporate income taxation and capital taxation more generally have become de
facto international taxes due to the mobility of the tax base, tax policy and
administration remain primarily a national responsibility.
All decisions on taxation in the
9
10
11
12
Evidence from behavioural economics shows that fairness (e.g. that the tax administration or the
government treat tax payers in a consistent and transparent way) is an important determinant of tax
morale. If anecdotal evidence in the public opinion suggests that some taxpayers receive a different
treatment or can easily avoid taxes, this might deteriorate the willingness to contribute to public
revenues via taxes in general. Alm and Torgler (2006) analyse in an empirical study a number of tax
morale determinants.
It is beyond the scope of this document to give a full overview of all contributions to the debate about
tax harmonization at the EU level. The main papers after the Neumark report are the Van den Tempel
Committee (1970) which called for a classical tax system for all Member States. The Werner Report
(1970) proposed tax harmonisation in the context of a monetary union. The 1971 and 1972 Council
resolutions called for fiscal harmonisation and in 1975 a proposal from the European Commission
suggested to harmonise corporate tax rates in a band between 45% and 55%. The Nyborg report (1979)
asked to harmonise tax bases prior to rates. Finally, the Ruding report proposed in 1992 some minimum
standards in corporate tax bases and a band for tax rates between 30% and 40%.
On the application of Recommendations C(2012)8805 and C(2012)8806, please see Annexes 2 and 3
which provide information on the work of the Platform on Tax Good Governance.
See de Moiij (2011) and European Commission (2015).
5
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
EU are taken unanimously in the Council. This has in practice limited the degree of co-
ordination and harmonization in this policy field in the EU as a whole as well as in the Euro
area. With the growing number of Member States, the unanimity rule in the tax area has
effectively reduced the chances of progress in legislation to safeguard national tax bases while
ensuring a smooth functioning of the single market.
This staff working document gives an overview of the reasons underlying tax
competition and its economic consequences in the EU while pointing at options to
mitigate the extent of tax avoidance activities.
At the root of the problem are the current
international rules for the distribution of taxable profits, the increase of capital mobility over
the last two decades and the lack of information and transparency on tax policies and
enforcement at the international level. The interplay of these factors creates incentives for
governments to compete for highly mobile tax bases, notably accounting profits as well as
income related to intangible assets, either by creating specific regimes with lower tax rates for
some types of income or via a decrease of the headline statutory tax rates. At the same time,
multinational companies use these structures as well as unintended mismatches between
countries tax systems to decrease their overall tax payments. The discussion of these issues in
this document is organised as follows: After this introduction, section 2 presents the results of
the stakeholder consultation held in April. Section 3 discusses the empirical evidence and the
theoretical arguments concerning the development of corporate income taxes in the EU in the
context of international tax competition. Section 4 presents possible options to deal with tax
avoidance activities.
In the light of the evidence for tax competition and profit shifting presented, the analysis
concludes that three areas of action could be envisaged to tackle the current problems in
the taxation of (large) multinational enterprises:
1. The first is an
integrated EU approach to the taxation of corporate income by
implementing a common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB)
at EU level
which would not only replace the current mechanism of taxing corporate profits with a
system based on attributing income where the real economic activity takes place as
measured by different factors (e.g. the number of employees, the sales and the capital
stock), but also eliminate the costly transfer pricing procedures since the tax base
would be consolidated at EU level.
2. The second are
measures focusing on the short term goal of stabilizing tax bases
aimed at closing existing loopholes and improve transfer pricing procedures. These
measures would also comprise ways to ensure a minimum level of taxation for specific
types of income as well as additional transparency measures such as an EU list of tax
havens.
3. The third area covers a broader topic and aims at
reforming the EU governance
structures in tax matters
to address taxation in a more transparent and effective way.
2.
C
ONSULTATION OF
I
NTERESTED
P
ARTIES
A stakeholder meeting was held on 13 April 2015 to discuss possible actions for inclusion
in the Action Plan. All stakeholders agreed that EU action on corporate taxation was
necessary and welcomed the Commission initiative.
Large business representatives and
professional services bodies stated that they strongly supported the existing CCCTB proposal,
and emphasised that it was important for them to retain optionality and consolidation. NGOs
and Small and Medium Enterprise (SME) business groups stated that although they would
largely prefer to retain consolidation, they were happy for this element to be postponed in the
6
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0007.png
interests of moving the proposal along. Both SMEs and NGOs were firm that the CCCTB be
made mandatory to prevent profit shifting. The discussion otherwise centred on Country by
Country Reporting (CbCR), with NGOs and SME groups arguing for swift progress on
adopting public CbCR, while larger businesses and professional services groups supported the
need for a full Impact Assessment to be conducted. NGOs also asked for the commission to
assess the impact on developing countries of tax avoidance by MNEs based in the EU,
including undertaking a "spill-over analysis".
Those Member States which spoke at the event supported making the CCCTB
mandatory and supported postponing consolidation.
The majority were in favour of
focussing discussions in the short term on international aspects on the CCCTB. Several
Member States voiced their support for agreeing a minimum effective tax rate, in particular in
the context of EU directives. Others reflected that tax rates were an important tool for some
countries, and their needs to be taken into account. On CbCR, the Member States which
spoke supported the need for an Impact Assessment on the costs and benefits of the various
options. Member States stressed that the Action Plan should also reflect the need to build on
the advantages of the Internal Market and provide incentives for businesses to grow. In
particular, many Member States were interested in improving the Arbitration Convention.
3.
3.1.
T
AX
C
OMPETITION IN THE
E
UROPEAN
U
NION
The Root of the Problem: Where are Profits taxed?
Tax competition
broadly defined as the uncooperative setting of taxes where a country
is constrained by the tax setting behaviour of other countries
13
is mainly discussed in
corporate income taxation.
14
The reason is that governments consider that they are
competing with this tax for internationally mobile resources often connected to multinational
companies and these are usually taxed as corporations. The two mobile resources are (1) real
investments (foreign direct investment) and (2) book profits (taxable profits attributed to a
country according to the current system of separate accounting and arm's length pricing).
15
3.1.1.
The Basic Mechanism
In an ideal world, the profits derived from the investment of a multinational company in
a specific country could be clearly observable and attributable to real activity in that
country.
In reality, the distribution of taxable profits poses considerable problems. When the
economic activity of a company or a group is taking place in two countries the question arises
how to divide the taxable profits from the activity between two jurisdictions while at the same
time assuring that there is no double taxation (or double non-taxation).
16
13
14
15
16
See Devereux and Loretz (2013).
There are other examples of tax competition for example in the area of the income taxation of very high
incomes (e.g. sports stars as analysed in Kleven et al. (2013)) or in cross-border shopping (for example
differences in consumption taxes as analysed in Nielsen (2001)). However, it is usually considered to be
limited to relatively small groups of employees or consumers compared to the extent of tax avoidance
observed in corporate taxation.
The separation between real investment and book profits also seems to serve as rough benchmark in
what is considered to be harmful tax competition. Generally, preferential regimes are in their nature
more related to attraction of book profits. In practice it is however difficult to draw an exact line
between these types of competition.
For a discussion of the current issues with the international tax rules see Devereux and Vella (2014).
The basic problems are by no means new. Seligman (1895) describes this problem by saying that „We
live in an age of industrial complexity and differentiation. In former times property rights were simple,
and the little capital that existed was largely owned by the producer. To-day not only does the same
7
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0008.png
The system of international coordination of taxation assigns taxable profits based on the
idea that economic activity should serve as the measure for distribution.
To determine the
economic activity in a tax jurisdiction the subsidiary of a multinational firm is for tax
purposes treated as a single company. This company uses separate accounting with arm's-
length pricing for intra-firm transactions. A system of bilateral tax agreements is in place to
avoid double taxation. The current system builds on the work of the League of Nations in the
1920s and that of the OECD after the Second World War.
The bases for the current distribution of taxable profits are the source and the residence
concepts.
17
The basic idea is that the country of source – the country where an international
company (a subsidiary of a multinational) produces and exchanges goods and services with
national companies and households – has the right to tax the profits from these activities. The
country of residence – where the owner of the company resides (either individual shareholders
or another company) – has in contrast the right to tax the world income of its resident namely
income in the form of dividends or interest.
3.1.2.
The Challenges due to Globalization
The distribution mechanism has come under pressure due to the changes in the
economic and business environment over the last decades.
For source countries, notably
when they are highly integrated internationally as is the case for EU Member States, the
activities of hosted companies are not limited to national borders. Inputs are imported from
other countries and not limited to national suppliers. Products and services produced are
exported and not only serve the market where a company is a tax resident. The same holds
true for the payments to owners which are spread over different countries. These payments
can either be transformed into interest or dividends or be diverted across countries to
minimize tax burdens. On top of this, source and residence based taxation also overlap and the
same company can have both source and residence characteristics in one country. Graph 1
illustrates the increased importance of cross border activities using data on foreign direct
investment stocks between the EU, the Euro Area and the rest of the world between 1995 and
2013. The steep increase in stocks since 1995 and during the first decade of the 2000s
underlines the increased importance of multinational company activities.
The growing importance of intangible assets and the digital economy has further
increased the pressure on national tax systems.
The growing share of intangibles assets
(patents, brands, firm-specific knowledge and technologies) in the value creation of
multinational companies has increased tax competition. While the (re)location of these assets
is easier than for tangible (e.g. machinery, factories) assets, estimating their true economic
values and the real values of payments for their use is very complicated and sometimes even
impossible given the lack of comparable third party transactions. Despite the fact that the
digital economy or more precisely the overall development of the internet and communication
technologies plays an important role in this, the view of most experts is that the problem is not
capitalist invest in different enterprises, not only is the producer often dependent for a part of his
capital on sums that belong to others, but the old geographical unity has been dissolved, and there is no
necessary connection between the residence of the capitalist and the place where his capital is
employed. A system of taxation, therefore, which may have been perfectly just under the older and
simpler conditions, may now be entirely inadequate because of the failure of government to take
account of these new complications in property rights.“
Jogarajan (2013) notes based on this quote that
the basic issues remain essentially the same in today's global discussions about the taxation of
multinational companies.
For a more detailed discussion on the limits of the current system see Schön (2009). For a description of
the current system see the OECD Model Tax Convention.
17
8
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0009.png
limited to one sector but is of a more general nature. Solving the overall problems will
therefore also address the concerns regarding the digital sector.
18
Graph 1: FDI stocks relative to the rest of the world, EU-28 and Euro area, 1995–2013
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
EU28 (Outbound)
EU28 (Inbound)
Euro area (Outbound)
Euro Area (Inbound)
Source: UNCTAD (2014)
3.1.3.
The Tax Policy Reaction
As a consequence, Member States struggle to tax profits, which derive from economic
activity carried out by international companies on their territory.
To put it differently, the
international taxation rules struggle with distributing taxable profits based on the notion of
economic activity since it has become more and more difficult to trace the value creation
process with a territorial approach. Countries compete with each other by creating regimes
that attract mobile tax bases. The basic problem is that jurisdictions that compete for capital
via their tax system do not take into account the fiscal externalities their actions create in
other countries. Although the results of the literature are not conclusive, this lack of
coordination might ultimately lead to welfare losses. Box 1 provides a brief review of the
theoretical arguments.
The developments have led to a typical tax reform described as
tax-rate-cut-cum-base-
broadening
where governments have decreased corporate tax rates while broadening the
base to mitigate revenue losses.
19
Since profit shifting is largely driven by tax rate
differentials (see Box 2 for a more detailed explanation), this policy is from a national
perspective a reasonable policy response to the lack of coordination at the international
level.
20
Graph 5 shows the strong decrease of statutory rates since 1995 in the EU and third
18
19
20
For a detailed account of the role of taxation and the digital economy for tax competition see the report
of the Commission Expert Group on Taxation of the Digital Economy (2014). The report states that
"there should not be a special tax regime for digital companies. Rather the general rules should be
applied or adapted so that “digital” companies are treated in the same way as others."
http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/gen_info/good_governance_matters
/digital/report_digital_economy.pdf.
Nevertheless, base broadening has been less common than rate reduction. See the Annex to this SWD.
The basic theoretical model for the observation that profits shifting is driven by tax rate differentials can
be found in Haufler and Schjelderup (2000). Empirical evidence for this profit shifting via transfer
prices is reported in section 3.2.3.
9
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0010.png
countries and evidence for base broadening policies is presented in Annex 1. It should be
noted that base broadening as such is not harmful. Quite to the contrary, in some areas tax
policies promoting broad bases and lower rates are in fact recommended since they tend to
minimize the distortionary effects of taxation.
21
21
For example, the Commission argues in favour of such policies in the annual growth survey with a
focus on reducing exemptions and loopholes. A case in point are exemptions in value-added taxation
and tax expenditures in personal income taxes and corporate taxes.
10
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0011.png
Box 1: Tax competition and welfare
This Box gives an overview why the differential treatment of some forms of companies and capital might be a concern
from a welfare point of view and why it could be even beneficial in some cases.
Tax competition can lead to an undersupply of public goods.
In general, if countries engage in tax competition to
attract perfectly mobile capital, a source-based tax on capital may trigger a capital outflow and the burden of the tax
would be then entirely shifted onto the local production factors. Ultimately, this would lead to an under-provision of
public goods. In this case, tax harmonization would be always beneficial. A coordinated increase of the taxation of
capital would indeed determine an increase of public spending towards the efficient levels leading to an
unambiguously positive effect on welfare.
Tax competition may also tilt the choice of the tax mix with a higher burden borne by the immobile production
factor.
This theoretical prediction that capital mobility leads to a situation where the economic incidence of taxes on
mobile production factors will ultimately fall on the immobile factor is supported by the empirical evidence presented
below. An interesting question in this context is whether the new international rules for information exchange will
have an impact on the mobility of the capital tax base.
Tax competition may distort the allocation of capital between countries of different size.
Where countries differ in
size as measured by the number of inhabitants - not because these individuals differ in income or preferences – large
countries tend to have higher rates than smaller countries. The reason is that large countries can affect the after-tax
return to capital while small countries cannot. The result will be an inefficient allocation of capital between large and
small countries. This reinforces the case for coordination or harmonization, but it also makes coordination more
difficult from a political point of view because small countries benefit relatively more from tax competition in terms of
capital inflows and higher service and public spending than large countries.
Another welfare cost of tax competition is related to its effects on public redistributive policies.
These policies could
be characterized as insurance against specific risks such as unemployment or illness. If tax competition undermines the
ability of governments to provide such insurance this will have social costs.
The strong predictions of the standard models of tax competition have been refined by numerous other
contributions in the literature.
Overall, the effects of tax competition on the provision of public goods and the size of
public sector, the tax system, and ultimately on welfare are complex and depend on many elements.
Relaxing the assumption of a fixed capital stock introduces into the picture the links between a certain economic
area and the Rest of the World.
In the standard models of tax competition, the capital stock is assumed to be fixed. In
reality, the supply of capital is elastic. Therefore, a reduction of capital taxation will not only attract capital from other
jurisdictions in an economic area, but also from the Rest of the World. This implies that the aggregate efficiency costs
of tax competition will be in general reduced with respect to the standard models. These considerations are directly
relevant for the European Union. The most obvious implication is that in tackling the "internal" tax competition
process, it is important to keep in mind the "external" dimension as well, in order to avoid hampering the
attractiveness of the EU for investment from the rest of the world.
Important refinements of the standard models consider the case of imperfect competition and the possibility of
economic rents, both firm- and location-specific.
In general, standard results discussed above still hold if these rents
are firm-specific. Indeed, in this case there will be the incentive for the governments to engage in tax competition to
attract the firms generating these rents. This is not the case anymore for location-specific rents. Following this line of
reasoning, smaller countries could be more active in tax competition if they have a little potential for location-specific
rents.
In the new geography models, location specific rents derive from agglomeration economies.
These models provide a
very different view of tax competition. The reduction of production costs due to agglomeration leads to spatial
concentration of production facilities in "core countries" whose residents demand high levels of public services. This
allows higher tax rates on capital income because agglomeration economies generate rents that can be taxed.
Therefore, in these models tax harmonization is in general not desirable. For instance, core countries would have to
reduce public services to inefficiently low levels.
11
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0012.png
Box 1: Tax competition and welfare (continued)
Profit shifting may have different effects on tax competition for investment.
Profit shifting may strengthen tax
competition, since countries will be concerned about the revenue losses that may derive from it. But it may also reduce
tax competition by decreasing the sensitivity of FDI to corporate taxation (see Sec. 3.2.2). Policymakers may therefore
face a trade-off in dealing with tax avoidance and profit shifting. On the one hand, they may want to secure tax
revenues as much as possible by setting in place anti-avoidance tools. On the other hand, they may want to keep or
increase the attraction of the country for multinationals. One obvious way to deal with this trade-off could be
differentiating the taxation of multinationals and domestic firms, recognizing the former are more mobile that the
latter. This could be achieved not only directly, but also indirectly if tax planning devices are available
de facto
only to
multinationals via for instance issuing specific regulations, rulings, or lax enforcement.
In some cases tax competition could even have welfare-improving effects.
The most important early contribution is
Brennan and Buchanan (1980). Their basic idea is that without tax competition the size of the public sector would be
excessive. Tax competition would be then beneficial because it would limit the tendency of governments to the
overexpansion. The incentive to an overprovision of public goods could derive specifically from the fact that capital is
not perfectly mobile for the simple reason that once it is installed it is costly to be moved. Therefore, government may
try to tax it. Tax competition may limit this incentive.
The competition for mobile capital has also created strong incentives to create
preferential regimes where governments tax specific mobile bases at a lower rate than
domestic bases.
The reason is that in order to limit revenue losses it is attractive to tax mobile
bases lighter than immobile (domestic) ones. In economic terms, a government sets the tax
rate in response to the elasticity of the tax base.
22
The easier the tax base moves out of the
country, the lower the tax rate in the preferential regime will be. The existence of preferential
regimes was limited by international policies aiming at reducing this type of regimes
generally considered as being harmful forms of tax competition.
23
One should note though
that removing these regimes increases the pressure to compete for tax bases with the statutory
rate. The reasons is that the government loses one policy tool when these regimes are
abolished and will need to readjust its overall system leading to an overall lower taxation of
corporate profits irrelevant whether they are mobile or not.
22
23
The basic theoretical argument for this observation was made in a very clear way by Keen (2001). He
concludes,
"preferential regimes may serve a useful strategic purpose in enabling countries to confine
their most aggressive tax competition to particular parts of the tax system."
The prominent example at the EU-level is the Code of Conduct for business taxation.
12
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0013.png
Box 2: Profit shifting
Multinational companies can exploit differences in tax rates by shifting profits from a high tax to a low tax country. The
gain from shifting profit is the tax rate differential. If the tax rate in country A is 30% and the tax rate in country B is 5%,
the gain for each Euro taxable profit shifted is 25 cents. There are different ways of shifting profits. The most common
are transfer price manipulation, intra-firm debt shifting and intellectual property location.
Transfer price manipulation occurs by manipulating the price of cross-border deliveries, services and other transactions
between related companies. The transfer price is a cost to the company receiving the delivery or service and reduces
the profit of that company. On the other hand, it is an income to the providing company and it increases the profits of
that company. Therefore a high transfer price leads to low profits in the receiving company and high profits in the
providing company. If profits are taxed at a lower rate in the country of the receiving company, a low transfer price can
reduce the total amount of payable tax without changing total pre-tax profits. Although transactions between related
companies should be priced as if they were concerning a third party (arm's length principle), there is some flexibility in
the methods and imprecision in the data used for determining transfer prices. Also there is some room for related
companies to structure their transactions. This flexibility can be used by multinational companies to reduce the amount
of payable tax. The mechanism is illustrated in the following table:
Base
Parent
(country B)
Turnover
Costs
Profit (before tax)
Tax rate
Payable tax
100
70
30
5%
1.5
Subsidiary
(country A)
70
50
20
30%
6
7.5
Total
Parent
(country B)
100
60
40
5%
2
Alternative A
Subsidiary
(country A)
60
50
10
30%
3
5
Total
170
120
50
160
110
50
In the base scenario, a parent company in country B sells finished products for 100 units. It buys intermediary products
from a subsidiary in country A for 70 units. This is the arm's length price, consisting of a cost of 50 and a profit mark-up
of 20. The parent has no other costs. Now, the total pre-tax profit of the multinational is the sum of the profits of the
parent, 30 and those of the subsidiary, 20. In total, the pre-tax profits are 50. 30 is taxed at 5% and 20 is taxed at 30%,
leading to a total payable tax of 7.5. If there are no easy comparable goods to determine the arm's length price of the
intermediary product, the company could change the conditions of delivery or argue for a lower mark-up reduce the
price of the intermediate product to 60 (Alternative A). While total pre-tax profits remain unchanged, the profits of the
parent are increased to 40 and the profits of the subsidiary are reduced to 10. A profit of 10 has been shifted from the
subsidiary to the parent and, as a consequence, from high-tax country A to low-tax country B. As a result, the total
payable tax is reduced by 2.5 to 5.
Another mechanism for cross-border profit shifting is debt shifting. Multinational companies have large freedom in
establishing intragroup financial relations. By using internal loans instead of internal equity, they can convert income
streams from dividends to interest. As dividends are usually taxed in the source country and interests in the residence
country this leads to a shift of profits. This is illustrated in the table overleaf.
13
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0014.png
Box 2: Profit shifting (continued)
Assume the same base scenario as in the table above. The parent company fully owns the subsidiary company. The
subsidiary is fully financed by equity provided by the parent company. Net profits from the subsidiary are repatriated
to the parent. According to the DTC between country A and country B dividends from country A are exempt from
additional taxation in country B (participation exemption).
Base
Parent
(country B)
Earnings (before
interest and taxes)
Interest
Taxable Profit
Tax rate
Payable tax
Net profit
Repatriated
dividend
Net profit after
repatriation
30
Subsidiary
(country A)
20
Total
Parent
(country B)
30
Alternative B
Subsidiary
(country A)
20
Total
50
50
0
30
5%
1.5
28.5
14
0
20
30%
6
14
-14
0
50
15
45
5%
-15
5
30%
1.5
3.5
-3.5
0
50
7.5
42.5
0
2.25
42.75
3.5
3.75
46.25
0
42.5
46.25
In this case the payable taxes are identical to the ones in the previous example: 1.5 in country A and 6 in country B.
Now consider an alternative situation (Alternative B) in which the subsidiary still is fully financed by the parent
company, but part of this financing has taken the form of a loan. Assume that the value of the loan is 150 and the
yearly interest to be paid 15. Note that this internal loan does not have to have consequences for the external
financing of the multinational company. Now, the transfer of income from the subsidiary to the parent takes two
forms: interest and dividends. The interest paid from the subsidiary is deductible in country A and taxed in country B.
The dividend is taxed in country A and exempt in country B. So, by increasing the debt of the subsidiary, the
multinational has shifted 15 units of profits from country A to country B. This leads to a reduction of payable tax from
7.5 to 3.75.
The mechanism of profit shifting through the use of royalties is very similar. If the subsidiary company is using
intangible assets of which the property rights are in the hand of the parent, a stream of royalties from the subsidiary to
the parent will emerge. This stream will reduce profits in the source country (country A) and increase them in the
residence country. An arm's length price of these royalties is almost impossible to assess.
14
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0015.png
3.2.
3.2.1.
Empirical Evidence
Development of Corporate Income taxation
The dynamics of the statutory and effective tax rates provide insights about the tax
competition process.
24
The decision of a multinational company to engage in profit shifting
depends on the difference between the statutory tax rates between countries.
25
This difference
is the gain that can be obtained by shifting profits from a high to a low tax jurisdiction. By
contrast, other tax rate measures such as the effective average tax rate (EATR) impact the
decision where to locate an investment, while the size of an existing investment depends on
the effective marginal tax rate (EMTR) in a country. In line with the
tax-rate cut-cum-base-
broadening policy
described above, Devereux and Sørensen (2006) find a clear downward
trend in the statutory tax rates for the EU-15 and G-7 countries. They also find a decline of the
EATR since the 1980s and a certain stability of the EMTR for the period 1982-2001, followed
by a reduction in the 2000s. These developments are consistent with two explanations for tax
competition which are not mutually exclusive. First, the decrease of the statutory rate is due to
the existence of tax competition for mobile book profits and countries reduce rates to be less
exposed to profits shifting. Second, the decrease in the EATR is a result of tax competition for
mobile firms (investments) since the decision on where to locate is based on the average tax
payment on all profits generated by the project. Graph 2 shows the development of the
statutory tax rate for more recent years and confirms this downward trend until the beginning
of the crisis when statutory tax rates levelled off. Table 1 gives the values for other tax rate
measures which show again the same pattern as identified by Devereux and Sørensen (2006).
Graph 2: Statutory CIT rates, 1995-2014
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
EU-28
EA-18
OECD-7
BRIC
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
24
25
There exists a large empirical literature focusing on tax competition. According to the survey by
Devereux and Loretz (2012), the studies can be classified in three groups. Some papers look at the
dynamic of tax rates and tax revenues; other papers analyse the tax rates and tax revenues of a country
based only on factors from that country; finally, some studies try to assess the extent to which the
choices of tax rates in a country depend on the choices in other countries.
It should be noted that while the difference in statutory tax rates are one piece of evidence for tax
competition, differences in the effective rates are equally important. Effective rates capture not only the
existence of varying tax rates but also – and in some cases even more importantly – the existence of
loopholes and preferential regimes.
15
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0016.png
Graph 3: Statutory CIT rates, maximum EU-28, unweighted averages EU-28, EA-18, EU-15
and NMS, minimum EU-28, 1995-2014
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
max
EU-15
EA-18
EU-28
NMS
min
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
The development of the average statutory rates in the EU masks the fact that there are
considerable differences between Member States.
Graph 3 shows the average rate in the
EU as well as the lowest and the highest statutory rates. It shows that the discrepancies in
terms of rates are substantial. In 2014, the highest rate is 38 % in France and the lowest rate is
10 % in Bulgaria. The graph also shows that while there was some convergence in rates at the
beginning of the millennium, this process seems to have come to an end and rates are even
diverging. It should be noted that low statutory rates are not an issue as such. To the contrary,
lower rates can also be considered as being investment and growth friendly. The point of the
analysis here is to show that a lowering of rates has occurred in many countries. In this
document there is no evaluation or consideration on what statutory tax rate level is optimal.
Table 1: Change of average CIT rate, effective average tax rate, effective marginal tax rate,
1998 – 2014 in percentage points
1998-2000
CIT rate
26
EATR
EMTR
-2.0
-1.7
-1.9
2000-2005
-6.1
-4.3
-1.4
2005-2010
-2.1
-2.0
-2.5
2010-2014
-0.3
0.1
0.8
Total 1998-2014
-10.4
-8.0
-4.9
Source: ZEW(2014) and Commission services
The relative stability of statutory and effective tax rates in Europe over the last five
years does not necessarily imply reduced tax competition.
Recent data in table 1 show a
slower decrease of tax rate indicators and a certain stability of the average statutory tax rates
and forward-looking effective tax rates at the EU-level after the crisis.
27
Although the
stabilization of rates might be interpreted as less intense tax competition, this development
can also be explained by other factors. Indeed, the decrease of the CIT statutory tax rates has
some limits for several reasons related to the (domestic) functions of CIT as described in box
26
27
To keep the table consistent, in this table CIT rate data from ZEW are being used. These differ slightly
from those published in Taxation Trends in EU-Member States.
See also Annex 1 to this Staff Working Document.
16
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0017.png
3. First, if the corporate tax is considered as a backstop for personal income tax and a
withholding tax for capital income, by decreasing the CIT rate the tax avoidance incentives to
re-characterize personal income as corporate income are strengthened with possible negative
consequences on total tax revenues. Graph 4 illustrates the correlation between the two rates.
Second, the CIT covers not only mobile firms and their profits, but also immobile (domestic)
firms and profits. For this reason there is an incentive for governments to create preferential
regimes with lower rates for mobile profits while applying the higher headline rate to
domestic profits. However, this policy can only be applied within the limits of the Code of
Conduct and the State Aid rules. As a consequence, tax competition via the headline rate may
increase, if preferential regimes are not allowed. Finally, there could be political constraints
for the reduction of the tax rate on corporations, especially given the strong political argument
that corporations ought to pay their fair share of tax.
Graph 4: Correlation between top CIT and PIT rates in 2014
40
FR
35
30
25
CIT rate
20
15
10
5
0
0
10
20
30
PIT rate
BG
HU
RO
LT
EE
CZ
SK
PL
LV
MT
LU
IT
DE
EL
BE
ES
PT
AT NL DK
SE
UK
HR FI
SI
CY
IE
40
50
60
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
17
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0018.png
Box 3: Why corporate income is taxed.
Why do governments generally tax corporations if the corporate income tax creates numerous problems?
Corporate taxes have to be paid by real people meaning either by shareholders via lower returns, by employees and
managers via lower wages or by consumers via higher prices. Who in fact bears the burden (the economic incidence) of
the tax is the subject of extensive research, and evidence suggests that - in line with tax competition theory predictions -
immobile factors such as labour carry the economic burden at least partly. The question then arises why not to tax
directly the different stakeholders in a company instead of levying a distorting tax on a legal entity?
There are a number of political and economic explanations for the use of corporate income taxes as a revenue
raiser, notably its function as a backstop to the personal income tax.
The most important reason is related to a purely
domestic function of the corporate income tax, namely that it serves as a backstop to the personal income tax.
Governments have not only an incentive to keep the corporate income tax, but also to make sure that the difference
between the corporate tax rate and the personal income tax rate is not too large. The reason is that there is otherwise an
incentive to reclassify labour income as capital income to reduce the tax burden. Slemrod (2004) shows empirically that
the backstop function is an important driver of the corporate income tax rate. Graph 4 shows the correlation between
corporate and personal income tax rates for the EU member states for 2014 that is in line with the empirical findings in
the literature.
Another important reason for corporate taxation is based on an administrative argument where the corporate tax
serves as a withholding tax on capital income at source.
The taxation of capital income at source (i.e. at the level of
the company) is an effective way to ensure that shareholders pay capital taxes. It should be noted that this does imply
anything about the economic incidence of the tax. The idea is rather that in a tax system with a comprehensive tax base a
withholding tax at the corporate level might be easier to enforce than taxing the capital income at the shareholder level.
A related argument is the popular view that corporate income taxes should be part of a progressive tax system.
While the relation between the corporate income tax and the overall progressiveness of the tax system is not clear (from
an economic perspective progressivity should be implemented in the personal income tax which also comprises capital
income), this idea is popular and also politically appealing. Here again the issue of who bears the burden of the corporate
income tax is important. One could argue that the low taxation of some corporate profits can increase gains for specific
groups for example via higher capital gains and therefore higher assets. While clear evidence on this particular link is
missing, the fact that high wealth households hold the largest share of financial assets might raise distributional concerns.
The tax payments of corporations have the character of a benefits tax.
This argument states that companies benefit
from the provision of public goods by the governments such as public infrastructure, a legal system and the provision of
a specific legal form for companies as well as the availability of skilled labour. Since company use these resources, the
argument goes, they should also contribute to its financing. While the argument is very compelling, it is less clear why
companies should contribute based on profits since also a loss making company uses these public goods. Nevertheless,
the benefit tax is usually considered one reason for taxing corporates.
The corporate tax falls at least partly on economic rents.
Taxing pure profits (only) is economically efficient since a
pure profit tax collects revenues without taxing an investment at the margin. In reality, corporate income tax systems do
not meet this objective, unless the tax base is calculated based on cash flows. While most CIT systems also burden
marginal investment, they do at least partly also fall on pure economic rents.
Limits to a decrease of the headline statutory tax rates may reinforce the incentives for
countries to enact preferential tax regimes at the boundaries of what is and what is not
allowed under rules of the Code of Conduct and to attract profits and multinationals by
issuing specific regulations and by rulings, allowing
de facto
mobile firms the reduction
of the tax burden.
The
standard
forward-looking effective tax rates do not reflect
preferential tax regimes, specific regulations and rulings. This may explain the stability of the
average statutory tax rates and forward-looking effective tax rates. Graph 5 shows with the
example of patent boxes that the levelling off of tax rates since 2007 has been accompanied
by an increase of the regimes providing lower tax rates for profits from these sources.
28
28
A patent box is a company tax regime which offers a lower tax rate for income from various types of
intangible property (IP), such as royalties from patents. The reference to a 'box' comes from the idea of
royalties being separated from the rest of the corporate income of the company and given preferential
treatment.
18
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0019.png
Graph 5: Number of Member States offering IP boxes and average reduction of rates
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
120%
100%
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
number of Member States
average reduction (right hand scale)
Source: Joint Research Centre - TAXUD
Empirical studies focusing on the determinants of corporate tax systems such as
globalization, capital mobility and strategic interaction between governments show
evidence of tax competition.
The main theoretical prediction here is that increasing
globalization and capital mobility should put a downward pressure on source-based taxes on
corporate income. In line with this prediction, there appears to be a statistical significant
negative relationship between forward looking effective tax rates and statutory tax rates and
measures of openness.
29
A more direct way to test for tax competition is to look directly at the
strategic interaction between tax variables set by different countries. Also these studies
generally confirm the existence of tax competition. For instance, Devereux et al. (2008) focus
on OECD countries over the period 1982 – 1999 and find evidence of strategic behaviour both
for statutory tax rates and effective marginal tax rates. Interesting empirical evidence does
exist for the strategic interactions between European countries highlighting the role of the
small countries located in the centre of Europe and of the new Member States.
30
At first sight, it is therefore surprising that the revenue contribution of CIT at the
aggregate level has not changed significantly in recent years. In 2012, on average 6.5%
of tax revenue was collected from corporations in the EU-27 (2.6% of GDP).
Graph 6
shows the development of this share for the EU-27 and illustrates that movements in revenues
are due to the pro-cyclicality of the tax. However, this stability should not be misinterpreted
as if tax competition had no revenue impacts. The negative impact on revenues has been
reduced by a number of other factors. First, the base broadening has partly offset the impact
of lower rates.
31
Second, incorporation has increased and this increased the overall base.
32
29
30
31
See for instance Bretschger and Hettich (2005), Schwarz (2007) and Loretz (2007).
See Redoano (2007), Chatelais and Peryat (2008), Crabbé and Vandenbussche (2008) and Cassette and
Paty (2008).
Base broadening may have been the result of both deliberate policies (e.g. reduced investment tax
credits and depreciation) and the increase of profitability in the corporate sector due for instance to
globalization (see Becker and Fuest, 2007) and to the rising share of the financial sector in the economy
19
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0020.png
Third, the share of capital in income has increased since the beginning of the 1980s.
33
Lastly,
relatively low interest rates in recent years had limited the interest deductibility from the
corporate tax base which also had a base broadening effect. These effects do not only explain
the stability of tax revenues, they indeed raise the question why the share of corporate taxes in
total revenue has not increased over time.
Graph 6: CIT revenues to GDP, GDP growth, EU-27, EU-18, 1995-2012
4,0
3,0
4
2,0
1,0
0,0
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
GDP Growth EU-28 (rhs)
GDP growth EA-18
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
-1
9
-6
Tax competition will have an impact on the allocation of capital and profits across
jurisdictions.
These effects will depend on the sensitivity of these variables to tax
differentials across countries. Empirical evidence provides insights about the magnitude of
these effects. This empirical evidence will be discussed in the following paragraphs. Section
3.2.2 will discuss the relation between the allocation of physical capital and corporate tax
rates. Section 3.2.3 will go into profit shifting and its responsiveness to these rates.
3.2.2.
Mobility of capital
It is commonly agreed that capital has become more mobile over time and notably with
the introduction of the Euro.
Capital flows have increased substantially over time. In the
EU, on average outbound foreign direct investment (FDI) as a percentage of GDP was equal
to 0.64% in the 1970s, 1% in the 1980s, 2.6% in the 1990s, 4.9% in the period 2000-2007; it
has decreased to 2.8% in the period 2008-2013 as a consequence of the crisis.
34
There are
moreover clear market signals pointing to a high degree of capital mobility; for instance the
equalization across markets of the interest rates on deposits with similar features is a clear
indication in this sense. As regards the effect of the monetary union, Petroulas (2007)
provides econometric evidence that the introduction of the Euro increased inward FDI within
32
33
34
(see Devereux et al., 2004; Auerbach, 2007). Restricting the deductibility of interest payments is one
example for base broadening.
See De Mooij and Nicodeme (2008) for empirical evidence of the effects of income shifting from the
personal to the corporate tax base.
The development of the capital share and the labour share in income is analysed in Karabarbounis and
Neiman (2013). They find that the global labour share of income has decreased while the capital share
has increased. Among other reasons, notably changes in technology and relative prices of investment
goods have induced firms to shift from labour to capital use.
Source: UNCTAD (2014).
20
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0021.png
the Euro area by about 16%, from Euro Area members to other member states by 11% and
from non-Euro member states to Euro Area members by 8%.
35
The correlation between domestic savings and investment indicates increasing capital
mobility.
The "saving retention coefficient" – the part of domestic savings which is invested
domestically – seems to be decreasing over time, consistent with increased capital mobility.
For European countries these coefficients are much lower that the non-OECD countries and
have declined over time more rapidly.
36
Econometric evidence shows that FDI is sensitive to corporate taxation and that the
sensitivity may have increased over time.
This is in line with increased capital mobility. De
Mooij and Ederveen (2006) find that decreasing the host country's tax rate by one percentage
point would increase FDI by between 2 and 3.9% depending on the study characteristics. Feld
and Heckemeyer (2011) find lower effects, although still statistically significant.
37
Furthermore, also the location decision of multinational companies' investments is affected by
taxation.
38
Empirical evidence also suggests that a large share of the burden of corporate taxes is
shifted to immobile factors.
Again, this is in line with increased capital mobility. Indeed, the
theoretical literature provides clear predictions for the incidence of a source-based tax on
capital: the more mobile the capital is, the lower the tax burden on capital will be, since this
burden will be shifted onto other production factors.
39
Measuring the incidence of taxation is
however difficult and the results should be interpreted with caution. However, the existing
studies provide indication that capital is indeed very mobile. Arulampalam et al. (2008) find
for the period between 1993-2003 that in France, Italy, Spain and the UK about 60% of the
burden of the corporate income tax is borne by labour in the short-run and that labour bears all
the burden of the tax in the long-run. This means that for each additional Euro of corporate
tax, wages decrease by 60 cents. Fuest et al. (2013) find an incidence of 77% over the period
1998-2008 for Germany. Lower estimates for Germany are provided by Dwenger at al.
(2011). They find an incidence of between 19% and 29% relying on data for the period 1998
and 2006.
Note that the possibility of income shifting by multinationals tends to reduce the
mobility of real capital (FDI).
Tax avoidance could make FDI less sensitive to tax factors
since the burden of high tax rates could be avoided, affecting the mobility of "real" capital or
"real" profits as opposed to book profits.
40
35
36
37
38
40
Schiavo (2007) confirms these results in a different research setup.
See Feldstein and Bacchetta (1991), Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000) and Zodrow (2010).
Both studies are so called meta-studies. This means they summarize the results of numerous empirical
studies using statistical tools to derive a single estimate out of from all the estimates considered in the
meta approach.
See Barrios et al. (2012) for an analysis of the impact of withholding taxes on the investment location
decision. The authors also found that the complexity and multiplicity of bilateral country-tax rules
magnifies the tax savings international corporations can make through FDI decisions. A similar result
was found by van´t Riet and Lejour (2015).
This concern was also raised by Mario Monti in the report "A new Strategy for the single market"
which was prepared upon request of the European Commission. The report was published in 2010.
Monti stresses that the immobile factor labour is carrying some of the burden from competition.
See for instance Overesch (2009).
21
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0022.png
3.2.3.
Profit Shifting
Profit shifting is by its very nature difficult to measure. Estimates are subject to large
uncertainty and should be interpreted with caution.
41
The presence of affiliates in low-tax
countries by multinationals and the relatively lower tax rates based on accounting figures for
these affiliates may at best signal the possible existence of an issue, but they cannot be used to
infer the extent of the problem. Several reasons other than taxation can induce a multinational
to have a presence in some low-tax countries. Effective tax rates based on accounting figures
have received considerable attention in the media over the last years with the emergence of
the financial crisis. Very low effective tax rates on foreign profits were reported for well-
known corporations, especially of the digital economy, and were often compared with the
effective tax rate on domestic income
42
. However, conceptually the comparison of the
effective tax rates on foreign profits should be made with the unobservable effective tax rate
on foreign profits in the absence of profit shifting, rather than with the actual effective tax rate
on domestic income. More generally, these effective tax rates vary for several reasons and
depend for instance on the investment policy of a company – with the related depreciation
provisions - and tax loss carry forward.
43
Other concerns can be raised for those tax avoidance
aggregate measures based on the computation of "tax gaps" that do not distinguish between
international and domestic tax avoidance and for those measures that compute "theoretical"
tax liabilities without recognizing all those tax provisions entailing a reduction of taxation
such as R&D incentives and again capital allowances.
More robust evidence of profit shifting has to be necessarily indirect and builds on
different empirical estimation strategies,
such as comparing pre-tax profits of low and high-
tax affiliates, tracing the effects of an increase of profits in high-tax countries' affiliates on the
profits of low-tax countries' affiliates, and comparing in a proper way the tax payments of
multinationals and domestic companies. In the following paragraphs the results of the
different empirical approaches are presented.
Indirect evidence of profit shifting can be obtained by comparing the pre-tax
profitability of high- and low-tax affiliates and studies suggest that an increase of the
host country CIT rate of ten percentage points would lower affiliates pre-tax profits in
that country by 8%.
Theory predicts that tax avoidance will typically entail a decrease of
(pre-tax) profitability in the high tax country and a corresponding increase in the low tax
country. In fact, econometric studies confirm the existence of such a negative correlation
between corporate income tax and reported pre-tax profits. Heckemeyer and Overesch (2013)
41
42
43
For a recent survey see Riedel (2014). This section mainly draws on her paper. For another review of
the literature see also Dharmapala (2014). See also OECD (2013a). In the context of the OECD BEPS
Action Plan (Action 11), work has been carried out on indicators of scale and economic impact of
BEPS (OECD, 2013b).
The final report of the Expert Group on Taxation of the Digital Economy reports effective tax rates
based on accounting figures for the largest corporations of the digital economy and for the major non-
digital companies by market capitalization. Overall, it emerges that these effective tax rates are lower
for non-US income and that this pattern is more pronounced for the digital companies. For instance, for
Google (Apple) the effective tax rates on foreign profits are equal to 3.2% (2.5%), 5.3% (1.9%) and
8.6% (3.7%) for 2011, 2012 and 2013 respectively; the effective tax rates on US income are instead
equal to 49.9% (75.3%), 40.8% (70.2%) and 26.4% (61%) for the same years (see Expert Group on
Taxation of the Digital Economy, 2014, Report: 54-55).
Yahoo is an example of the difficulties in the interpretation of the accounting figures as measures of
effective taxation. Given some non-ordinary transactions in 2012 and 2013, the pattern found for the
other digital economy companies (with the effective tax rates on foreign profits considerably lower than
the rate on domestic profits) is for Yahoo completely reversed (see Expert Group on Taxation of the
Digital Economy, 2014, Report, page 54).
22
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0023.png
summarize the results of 238 estimates of the effects of corporate tax rates on reported profits
found in 25 empirical papers. They obtain a consensus figure for the tax semi-elasticity equal
to 0.8: An increase of the CIT rate of 10 percentage points (p.p.) lowers affiliates' pre-tax
profits by 8%.
These estimates of the sensitivity of profits to corporate tax rate differentials can in
principle be used to estimate the revenue losses due to profit shifting, but they have to be
interpreted with caution.
There could be reasons other than tax avoidance that generate a
(positive or negative) correlation between pre-tax profits and corporate income taxation. For
instance, a higher taxation in a country requires a higher pre-tax profitability in order to invest
in that country, and this generates a positive correlation between pre-tax profits and corporate
income taxation. As another example, a higher taxation in a country may determine a lower
effort provision by affiliates' managers in that country because less earned income could be
kept or "extracted" when taxation increases and this tends to generate a negative correlation
between pre-tax profits and corporate income taxation.
44
Econometric evidence on profit shifting can also be derived identifying unexpected
changes of profits in high-tax locations (shocks) and estimating how these are
transmitted to low-tax countries' affiliates.
This approach is used by Dharmapala and
Riedel (2013) who estimate that about 2% of the additional profits arising in a high-tax
country are transmitted to low-tax countries affiliates. The authors argue however that this is
likely to be only a lower bound of the profit shifting for issues related to their dataset and their
identification strategy.
Another estimation technique used to measure the size of profit shifting is to compare
the tax payments of multinational and similar domestic companies. Studies suggest that
this difference is about 30%.
Since these two categories of companies are different for
several reasons, the comparison of the tax payments is made only for those companies that are
identified through a statistical process of matching, and therefore that are "similar" from a
statistical point of view. In this way, the different tax payment can be attributed to the
different profit shifting possibilities related to the status of being a multinational or a domestic
company. Egger et al. (2010) use this estimation strategy and find that multinationals in
European high-tax countries pay about 32% less CIT than "matched" domestic companies.
This estimate is of the same order of magnitude of the 27% found by Finke (2013) for
Germany using the same econometric model. A word of caution is necessary however for
these studies as well. There could be unobservable aspects explaining the difference between
these two classes of companies and biasing therefore the results. For instance, to the extent
that governments deliberately try to attract multinationals granting them specific tax benefits,
the estimated gap would be partly attributable to factors other than tax avoidance.
A part of the empirical literature focuses on the importance of specific channels of profit
shifting. Overall, pricing of intra-firm transactions and strategic IP location seem to
explain about 70% of profit shifting.
The policy relevance of this empirical literature is
straightforward: by providing statistical information on the relative importance of the different
tax avoidance channels, it is possible to design correctly the anti-avoidance measures to
maximize their effectiveness, while at the same time minimizing the downside effects in
terms of compliance and administrative costs. The pricing of intra-group transactions, the
strategic location of IP, and the debt-shifting channel are all statistically important, although
44
See Riedel (2014).
23
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0024.png
in relative terms the first two channels account for more than two thirds of the overall profit
shifting activities (see graph 8).
45
Graph 8. The relative importance of the different profit shifting channels
28%
Transfer Pricing and
IP Location Channels
Debt-Shifting
Channel
72%
Source: Commission Services
a. Profit shifting via transfer pricing
Empirical analyses of tax-motivated transfer pricing show a significant impact of
corporate taxation on internal import and export prices.
The empirical evidence is
available for the US and some European countries. According to the estimates by Davies
et al.
(2014) for France, large multinationals and some tax havens play a crucial role in these profit
shifting activities. For European multinationals, Lohse and Riedel (2013) find robust evidence
of profit shifting. They also find that transfer pricing documentation and special transfer
pricing penalties are very effective in tackling the issue. Table 2 gives an overview of the
most important studies on the impact of transfer price manipulation and their results.
45
See Heckemeyer and Overesch (2013).
24
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0025.png
Table 2: Overview of studies analysing transfer price manipulation
Transfer pricing studies
Clausing
(2003)
Bernard et
al. (2006)
Cristea and
Nguyen
(2013)
Davies et al.
(2014)
Lohse and
Riedel
(2013)
US
(1997-1999)
US
(1993-2000)
Denmark
(1999-2006)
France
(1999)
Export prices
Wedge between arm's
length and intra-firm
prices
Export prices
Wedge between arm's
length and intra-firm
prices
Earnings Before
Interest and Taxes
-1 percentage point of CIT rate in the
destination country reduces export prices
by 1.8%
- 1 percentage point of CIT rate increases
the wedge by between 1.6 and 4.2%
Owning an affiliate in a low-tax country
reduces export prices by between 5.7% and
9.1%.
For exports in tax havens, intra-firm prices
are estimated to be 11% lower than arm's
length prices.
+ 10 p.p. of CIT rate decreases reported pre-
tax profits by 3.94%. Transfer pricing
documentation and special transfer pricing
penalties reduce profit shifting by around
50%.
+ 10 p.p. tax rate differential between
France and its trade partners reduces intra-
firm export prices by 2.2% and increases
intra-firm import prices by 2.4%.
Europe (1999-2009)
Vicard
(2014)
France
(2000-2012)
Intra-firm export and
import prices
Source: Commission Services
b. Profit shifting via the location of Intellectual Property
Recent econometric evidence shows the importance of profit shifting through the
strategic location of Intellectual Property (IP).
The corporate tax seems to affect IP in the
balance sheets, the patent applications, as well as the sensitivity of pre-tax profits to changes
of the CIT rate. As regards the location of IP, for instance, Karkinski and Riedel (2012) find
that an increase of 1 percentage point of the corporate tax rate reduces the number of patent
holdings by about 3.5%. The estimates in Böhm et al. (2012) for Europe indicate that the
probability of patent relocation to a tax haven is increasing with the value of the patent and
that controlled foreign company (CFC) - legislation may be effective in reducing this form of
profit shifting. Beer and Loeprick (2014) find that mandatory documentation requirements are
effective in reducing profit shifting by transfer pricing; this result does not hold for those
subsidiaries with large intangible assets. Table 3 summarizes the findings of recent studies on
the use of intangibles for profits shifting purposes.
25
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0026.png
Table 3: Overview of studies analysing intellectual property location
Intangible assets
Dischinger and
Riedel (2011)
Karkinski and
Riedel (2012)
Griffith et al.
(2014)
Europe
(1995-2005)
Europe
(1978-2007)
Europe
(1985-2005)
Intangible property in the
balance sheets
- 1 p.p. in the average tax difference to
all other group affiliates increases the
subsidiary's IP in the balance sheet by
about 1.7%
+1 p.p. of CIT rate decreases patent
applications by about 3.5%-3.8%
(depending on the empirical model)
+1 p.p. of CIT rate decreases patent
applications by about 0.5%-3.9%
(depending on the location)
Tax sensitivity of reported profits to 1
p.p. increase of the CIT rate increases
from 0.76% to 1.2% for subsidiaries
with an above median intangible
assets endowment.
An increase of 1 standard deviation of
patent value increases the probability
of patent relocation in a tax haven by
about 16%. This probability of patent
relocation in a tax haven is reduced by
about 1/3 by CFC legislation.
+ 1 p.p. of CIT rate decreases patent
applications by about 13.1%
(pharmaceutical), 1.5% (ICT sector)
and 5.4% (car sector). The presence of
patent boxes has a strong and
significant effect on patent
applications.
Patent holdings
Patent holdings
Beer and
Loprick (2014)
World (ORBIS)
(2003-2011)
Tax sensitivity of reported
profits and endowment of
intangible assets
Böhm et al.
(2012)
Europe
(1978-2007)
Probability of patent
relocation to tax haven and
effectiveness of CFC
legislation
Joint Research
Centre - TAXUD
(2015)
World (2000-
2011) top 2,000
corporate R&D
investors
Patent holdings
Source: Commission Services
c. Profit shifting via intra-firm debt
Multinational companies also shift profits by locating equity in low tax countries while
financing subsidiaries in high tax countries with intra-firm debt to benefit from the
deductibility of interest from the tax base.
The most recent evidence for Europe shows that
foreign-owned plants have a higher debt-asset ratio than domestically owned plants. This gap
increases with the CIT rate of the host country as shown by Egger et al. (2010). For German
multinationals, Schindler et al. (2013) find that in a group with two affiliates, a 10 p.p.
increase of the CIT rate in the high-tax country increases the debt-asset ratio by 4.6% in that
country and lowers it by 1.4% in the other country. 40% of the increases of the debt asset ratio
are due external debt, the rest to internal debt according to this study. Riedel (2014) finds that
the tax elasticities in the literature imply that on average an increase of 10 percentage points
of the CIT rate is associated with an increase of about 10% of the affiliated internal debt-ratio.
Table 4 gives and overview of empirical studies analysing the debt-shifting channel.
In conclusion, there is clear evidence of profit shifting activities by multinational
companies. The most important channels are transfer pricing manipulations and the use
of intangible asset location.
Debt shifting is a third channel but less important compared to
the other two. From a policy perspective this means that solutions to tackle the profit shifting
problem should concentrate in improving the consistency of transfer pricing and by reducing
incentives to shift income related to intangible assets.
26
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0027.png
Table 4: Overview of studies analysing intra-firm debt shifting
Debt-Shifting Channel
Desai et al.
(2004)
Huizinga et al.
(2008)
US
(1982-1994)
Europe
(1994-2003)
Debt/Asset
(internal and
external)
Debt/Asset
Debt/Asset
Ratio of
domestically
and foreign-
owned plants
Internal Debt
Ratio
Internal and
External
debt/asset
ratio
+10 p.p of CIT rate increases the affiliates' debt/asset
ratio by about 2.8% (about 1.9% for external debt and
3.5% for internal debt).
For a multinational with two affiliates, a 10 p.p. increase
of the CIT rate in one country increases the debt/asset
ratio by 2.4% in that country and lowers it by 0.6% in
the other country.
Foreign-owned plants exhibit a debt/asset ratio higher
than domestically owned plants by 1.7 p.p. This gap
increases with the CIT rate of the host country. + 1 p.p.
of CIT rate in the host country is associated with an
increase of the debt/asset ratio by 0.7 p.p.
+10 p.p. of tax rate difference with respect to the
lowest-tax affiliate increases internal debt ratio by
about 0.73%.
For a multinational with two affiliates, a 10 p.p. increase
of the CIT rate in the high-tax country increases the
debt/asset ratio by 4.6% in that country and lowers it by
1.4% in the other country. 40% of the increases of the
debt asset ratio are due external debt, the rest to
internal debt.
Egger et al.
(2010)
Europe
(1996-2004)
Büttner and
Wamser (2013)
Germany
(1996-2005)
Schindler et al.
(2013)
Germany
(1996-2006)
Source: Commission Services
4.
O
PTIONS
The interplay of the current distribution of taxable profits, higher capital mobility due
to globalization and digitalisation and the lack of a similar international integration of
tax policies can lead to tax competition and profit shifting.
The question is how the three
main roots of the problem (1) distribution of taxable profits, (2) increased capital mobility and
(3) insufficient co-ordination of tax policies at the international level can be addressed to
reach the objective to tax profits there where the economic activity takes place. Three areas of
action can be identified and are described in more detail in the action plan accompanying the
Communication and this Staff Working Document:
1.
The first action area would seek to replace the current system of distributing
taxable profits and create a more stable allocation rule.
The most obvious
candidate for this is the CCCTB. In economic tax research also the possibility of new
systems such as destination based cash-flow taxes are discussed.
2.
The second set of actions comprises measures which try to reform the current
international tax rules by closing loopholes and fixing issues in the current system
of separate accounting, arm's length pricing and bilateral tax agreements.
In this
area measures related to BEPS are covered as well as actions to improve transfer
pricing and the income flows related to intangible assets. The discussion about an
effective level of taxation would also fall in this category. The reason is that effective
tax levels would not generally change the distribution of taxable profits among
countries but - depending on the base chosen – they would rather impact the current
revenue allocation for specific income types.
3.
The last area is to improve the current way of working together at the EU level
on tax issues by reforming the governance structure and improve the overall
exchange of information.
This would not only increase the overall transparency of
27
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
tax discussions at the EU level and reduce possible information asymmetries between
tax administrations. A stronger overall information exchange on capital income (at the
corporate but also at the private level) could act as a break or even reduce the impact
of capital mobility.
28
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
R
EFERENCES
Alm, J and B. Torgler (2006) Culture differences and tax morale in the United States and in
Europe Journal of Economic Psychology Volume 27, Issue 2, April 2006, Pages 224–246
Arulampalam, W., Devereux, M.P. and G. Maffini (2012), "The direct incidence of corporate
income tax on wages," European Economic Review, vol. 56(6), pages 1038-1054.
Auerbach, A. (2007), "Why Have Corporate Tax Revenues Declined? Another Look",
CESifo
Economic Studies,
53(2), pp.153-171.
Barrios,S., H. Huizinga, L. Laeven and G. Nicodème, (2012), "International taxation and
multinational firm location decisions", Journal of Public Economics 96: 946–958.
Beer, S. and J. Loeprick (2014), Profit Shifting: Drivers of Transfer (Mis)pricing and the
Potential of Countermeasures, International Tax and Public Finance, forthcoming.
Bernard, A., B. Jensen, and P. Schott (2006), Transfer Pricing by U.S.-based Multinational
Firms, NBER Working Paper 12493.
Becker, J. and C. Fuest (2007), "Globalisation generates higher corporate tax revenues",
ETPF research paper.
Böhm, T., T. Karkinsky and N. Riedel (2012), The Impact of Corporate Taxes on R&D and
Patent Holdings, Paper Presented at the 2012 TAPES Conference in Oxford.
Bretschger, L. and F. Hettich (2005), "Globalization and International Tax Competition:
Empirical Evidence based on Effective Tax Rates",
Journal of Economic Integration
20(3):
530-542.
Büttner, T. and G. Wamser (2013), "Internal Debt and Multinationals’ Profit Shifting –
Empirical Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data",
National Tax Journal
66, 2013, 63-95.
Cassette, A. and S. Paty (2008), "Tax competition among Eastern and Western European
countries: With whom do countries compete?",
Economic Systems
32 (4): 307-325.
Chatelais, N. and M. Peyrat (2008), "Are Small countries leaders of the European tax
competition?", CES Working Paper 2008.58.
Crabbe, K. and H. Vandenbussche (2009), "Are Your Firm's Taxes Set in Warsaw? Spatial
Tax Competition in Europe", CEPR Discussion Papers 7159.
Clausing, K.A. (2003), Tax-Motivated Transfer Pricing and US Intrafirm Trade Prices,
Journal of Public Economics 87, 2207–2223.
Cristea, A. and D. Nguyen (2013), Transfer Pricing by Multinational Firms: New Evidence
from Foreign Firm Ownerships, mimeo.
Commission Expert Group on Taxation of the Digital Economy (2014), Final Report, 28 May,
Brussels
Davies, R.B., Martin, J., Parenti, M. and F. Toubal (2014), “Knocking on Tax Haven’s Door:
multinational firms and transfer pricing”, Oxford University Center for Business Taxation,
Working Paper 15/01
Desai, M., F. Foley and J. Hines (2004), A Multinational Perspective on Capital Structure
Choice and Internal Capital Markets, Journal of Finance 59, 2451–2487.
Devereux, M. P. and J. Vella (2014), “Are we heading towards a corporate tax system fit for
the 21st century?” Oxford University Center for Business Taxation, Working Paper 14/25.
29
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
Dharmapala, D. and N. Riedel (2013), "Earnings shocks and tax-motivated income shifting:
evidence from European multinationals",
Journal of Public Economics
97: 95-107.
Dharmapala, D. (2014). "What Do We Know About Base Erosion and Profit Shifting? A
Review of the Empirical Literature," CESifo Working Paper Series 4612.
De Mooij, R.A and S. Ederveen (2006), "What a difference does it make? Understanding the
empirical literature on taxation and international capital flows," European Commission,
Economic Papers 261.
De Mooij, R. and G. Nicodème (2008), "Corporate tax policy and incorporation in the EU,"
International Tax and Public Finance,
15(4): 478-498.
De Mooij, R. (2011), “Tax Biases to Debt Finance: Assessing the Problem, Finding
Solutions”, IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/11/11.
Devereux, M. P., R. Griffith and A. Klemm (2004), "Why has the UK corporate tax raised
somuch revenue",
IFS Working Paper 04/04.
Devereux, M.P. and P. B. Sørensen (2006), “The Corporate Income Tax: international trends
and options for fundamental reform”, European Commission, Economic Papers No. 264.
Devereux, M. P., Lockwood, B. and M. Redoano (2008), "Do Countries Compete over
Corporate Tax Rates?",
Journal of Public Economics
92: 1210-1235.
Devereux, M. P and Loretz, S. (2012), "What do we know about corporate tax competition?"
Working Papers 1229, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation.
Dischinger, M. and N. Riedel (2011), Corporate Taxes and the Location of Intangible Assets
within Multinational Firms, 2011,
Journal of Public Economics
95: 691-707.
Dwenger, N., Rattenhuber, P. and V. Steiner (2011), "Sharing the burden: empirical evidence
of corporate tax incidence", Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance, Working
Paper 2011–14.
Egger, P., W. Eggert and H. Winner (2010), "Saving Taxes through Foreign Plant
Ownership",
Journal of International Economics
81: 99–108.
Europäische Wirtschaftsgemeinschaft (1962) – Kommission: Bericht des Steuer- und
Finanzausschusses (Neumark Bericht).
European Commission (2001), Towards an Internal Market without tax obstacles.
(COM(2001) 582 final) and the accompanying Staff Working Document "Company Taxation
in the Internal Market" (SEC(2001) 1681.
European Commission (2014). Taxation Trends in the European Union. Data for the EU
Member States, Iceland and Norway. 2014 edition.
European Commission (2015), Green Paper: Building a Capital Market Union, Staff Working
Document SWD(2015) 13 final.
European Economic Community (1992), Report of the Committee of Independent Experts on
Company Taxation ("Ruding report").
Evers, L., H. Miller and C. Spengel (2014), "Intellectual property box regimes: effective tax
rates and tax policy considerations",
International Tax and Public Finance,
22 (3): 502-530.
Feld, L. and J.H. Heckemeyer (2011), "FDI and Taxation: A Meta-Study",
Journal of
Economic Surveys 25:
233-272.
30
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0031.png
Feldstein, M., and P. Bacchetta, 1991. “National Saving and International Investment”, in
Bernheim, D. B., and J.B. Shoven (eds.), National Saving and Economic Performance
University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL
Finke, K. (2013), Tax Avoidance of German Multinationals and Implications for Tax
Revenue Evidence from a Propensity Score Matching Approach, mimeo.
Fuest, C., Peichl, A. and S. Siegloch (2013), "Do higher corporate tax reduce wages? Micro
evidence for Germany", IZA DP No. 7390.
Griffith, R., H. Miller and M. O'Connell (2014), Ownership of Intellectual Property and
Corporate Taxation, Journal of Public Economics 112, 12-23.
Haufler, A. and G. Schjelderup (2000), ”Corporate tax systems and cross country profit
shifting”
Oxford Economic Papers, 52 (2): 306-325
Heckemeyer, J. H. and M. Overesch (2013), "Multinationals' profit response to tax
differentials: Effect size and shifting channels", ZEW Discussion Papers 13-045.
Huizinga, H., Laeven, L. and G. Nicodeme (2008), "Capital structure and international debt
shifting",
Journal of Financial Economics,
vol. 88(1): 80-118.
International Monetary Fund (2014), "Spillovers in International Corporate Taxation", IMF
Policy Paper, May 9.
Jogarajan, S. (2013) The drafting of the 1925 League of Nations Resolutions on tax evasion.
Conference Papers. Mimeo.
http://www.law.cam.ac.uk/faculty-resources/summary/sunita-
jogarajan-the-drafting-of-the-1925-league-of-nations-resolutions-on-tax-evasion/13625.
Joint Research Centre – TAXUD (2015), "Patent Boxes Design, Patents Location and Local
R&D", A. Alstadsæter, Barrios, S., Nicodème, G., A. Skonieczna and A. Vezzani
(contributors), European Commission.
Lohse, T. and N. Riedel (2013), "Do Transfer Pricing Laws Limit International Income
Shifting? Evidence from European Multinationals",
CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4404
Loretz, S. 2007, Determinants of Bilateral Effective Tax Rates: Empirical Evidence from
OECD Countries, Fiscal Studies 28 No. 2, pp. 227-249.
Nielsen, S. B. (2001), "A simple model of commodity taxation and cross-border shopping",
Scandinavian Journal of Economics,
103(4): 599-623.
Petroulas, P. (2007), "The effect of the euro on foreign direct investment",
European
Economic Review,
vol. 51(6): 1468-1491.
Karabarbounis, L. and B. Neiman (2014), "The Global Decline of the Labor Share",
The
Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Oxford University Press, vol. 129(1): 61-103.
Karkinsky, T. and N. Riedel (2012), "Corporate Taxation and the Location of Patents within
Multinational Firms",
Journal of International Economics,
88(1): 176–185.
Keen, M. (2001), “Preferential regimes can make tax competition less harmful”,
National Tax
Journal,
54(4): 757-762
Keen, M. and K.A. Konrad (2012), "International Tax Competition and Coordination",
Working Papers, Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance
Kleven, H.J., Landais, C. and E. Saez (2013), "Taxation and International Migration of
Superstars: Evidence from the European Football Market."
American Economic Review,
103(5): 1892-1924.
31
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff (2000), “The Six Major Puzzles in International Micro-
economics: Is There a Common Cause?”, in Bernanke, Ben S., and Kenneth Rogoff (eds.),
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, 339–390. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
OECD (2013a),
Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting,
Paris.
OECD (2013b),
Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting,
Paris.
OECD (2015),
BEPS Action 11: Improving the analysis of BEPS,
Public discussion Draft,
Paris.
Overesch, M., 2009. “The Effects of Multinationals’ Profit Shifting Activities on Real
Investments”,
National Tax Journal
62 (1): 5–23.
Redoano, M. (2007). “Fiscal Interactions among European Countries: Does the EU matter?”,
CESifo Working Paper 1952
Riedel, N. (2014). Quantifying International Tax Avoidance: A Review of the Academic
Literature University of Bochum, Paper Prepared for the European Tax Policy Forum
Schiavo, S. (2007). Common currencies and FDI flows, Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford
University Press, vol. 59(3), pages 536-560, July.
Schindler, D., Møen, J., Schjelderup, G. and J. Tropina, 2013. "International Debt Shifting:
Do Multinationals Shift Internal or External Debt? Annual Conference 2013 (Duesseldorf):
Competition Policy and Regulation in a Global Economic Order 79749, Verein für
Socialpolitik / German Economic Association
Schön, W. (2009). International Tax Coordination for a Second-Best World (Part I). World
Tax Journal, October 2009, p. 67-114.
Schwarz, P. (2007). "Does Capital Mobility Reduce the Corporate-labor Tax Ratio?",
Public
Choice 130:
363-380.
Seligman, E. R. A. (1895).
Essays in Taxation.
Macmillan and Co. New York, London.
UNCTAD (2014). Handbook of Statistics 2014.
van den Tempel, A.J. (1970)
Corporation tax and individual income tax in the European
Communities. Studies: Competition - Approximation of Legislation 15, 1970.
Commission of
the European Communities - Working Document.
van Riet, M. and A. Lejour, (2015), Ranking the Stars. Network analysis of bilateral Tax
treaties, CPB Discussion Paper 290, CPB, Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis.
Vicard, V. (2014). Transfer pricing of multinational companies and aggregate trade, mimeo.
ZEW (2014), Effective tax levels using the Devereux-Griffith methodology: Final Report
2014, TAXUD/2013/CC/ 120
Zodrow, G.R. (2010) “Capital mobility and capital tax competition”,
National Tax Journal,
63 (4, Part 2): 865–902.
Zucman, G. (2014) "Taxing across Borders; Tracking Personal Wealth and Corporate
Profits",
Journal of Economic Perspectives,
28(4): 121-48
32
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0033.png
A
NNEX
1
A1.1
S
TYLIZED FACTS ABOUT THE
CIT
IN THE
E
UROPEAN
U
NION
1995-2015
I
NTRODUCTION
This annex describes the evolution of the Corporate Income Tax in the 28 current
Member States of the European Union. It relates this evolution to earlier descriptions in
the economic literature.
The evolution of statutory corporate income taxes since the 1980's
has been described in many studies
46
. Devereux, Griffiths and Klemm identified in their 2002
paper a number of stylized facts. These were updated in 2004 by Devereux and Sorensen.
Their database ends in 2004 and describes some non-EU countries, but does not describe all
current EU Members. This annex focuses on the EU over the period 1995-2014. It partly
describes the same indicators as the aforementioned studies.
A1.2
T
HE
COUNTRIES
.
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
BRIC
2013
2014
EVOLUTION OF THE STATUTORY RATE IN THE
EU
COMPARED TO OTHER
Graph 1: Statutory CIT rates, 1995-2014
EU-28
EA-18
OECD-7
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
The worldwide reduction of statutory corporate income tax rates since the 1980s has
continued at least until 2007. After that year, the pace of reduction in Europe levelled
off.
Devereux and Sorensen established that 'statutory tax rates have fallen substantially since
the early 1980s; while the pace of reductions has varied over time, it appears to be continuing
(in 2004)'. Graph 1 shows that this decline has continued in the period 1995-2014, notably up
to 2007. In the EU, the reduction of the average CIT rate was stronger than in the other
regions under consideration. These are the OECD-7 (Australia, Canada, Japan, Switzerland,
Iceland, Norway and the USA) and the BRIC-countries (Brazil, Russia, India, and China).
The fact that rates have decreased more in Europe than in the other regions contributes to the
46
For an overview, see Devereux and Loretz (2012).
1
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0034.png
image
47
that the EU is the driving force of the competition behind these reductions. The
difference between the EU and notably the OECD-7 grew mainly in the period 2000 – 2005.
In that period, the decline in the OECD-7 and the BRIC-countries subsided, while the
decrease in the EU continued. After the crisis, the pace of the reductions in the EU receded,
while Canada and Japan introduced new reductions. The USA was one of the few countries
that did not change its rate over the considered period.
A1.3
T
HE EVOLUTION OF
C
ORPORATE
I
NCOME
T
AX REVENUES
The revenues of the Corporate Income Tax (CIT) show a volatile trajectory around 3
per cent of GDP and 8.5% of total tax revenues. Despite the reductions of the rates, the
structural level seems to be relatively stable.
Over the years, the development of the share
of CIT can be divided into five stages. The averages show a strong increase in the period 1995
– 2000, a moderate reduction in the period 2000 – 2003, a strong increase in the run-up to the
crisis in the period 2003 – 2007 and a steep decline during 2007-2009. After this decline the
share of CIT more or less stabilised at a level close to that of 1995. This indicates that the
share of CIT revenues is more or less stable. The volatility of CIT revenues is strongly related
to fluctuations of economic growth. Not only are profits very responsive to economic growth,
also the carry back of losses to earlier years can increase the reduction of CIT revenues during
periods of lower economic growth.
Graph 2: Average share of CIT revenues to GDP, GDP growth, EU-27, 1995-2012
4,0
3,5
3,0
2,5
2,0
1,5
1,0
0,5
0,0
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
GDP Growth (rhs)
EU-27
EA-18
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014), Eurostat
In 2014, the share of CIT revenues to GDP is highest in Luxemburg (5.3 % GDP),
Cyprus and Malta (both 6.3 % of GDP), while Greece, Slovenia and Lithuania receive
1.3 % or less of GDP from corporate income tax. Malta and Cyprus show the highest
increase of the revenue share. Slovakia, Bulgaria and Romania experienced a
considerable decline over the considered period.
This is shown in graph 3, which ranks the
Member State in descending order of their CIT to GDP rate in 2012. In 1995 this order looked
different. Slovakia had the highest share of Corporate Income Tax to GDP (6.6 %), followed
47
In their study Devereux and Loretz state that 'most of the newer contributions (to the tax competition
debate) see the European Union as driving force of tax competition'. (p.20).
2
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0035.png
by Luxemburg, Bulgaria, Czech Republic and Cyprus. Austria and Slovenia (0.5 % of GDP)
displayed the lowest share. Although the average share increased in the following period,
many New Member States watched the share of corporate income tax decline. In 2000,
Luxemburg (7.0 %) and Cyprus (6.2 %) had the highest share and the Baltic States (between
0.7 % and 1.6 %) and Slovenia (1.2 %) the lowest. In 2007, as the shares of corporate
revenues were at an all-time high, Luxemburg (5.3 %), Cyprus (6.8 %) and Malta (6.2 %) had
the highest shares and Estonia
48
(1.6 %), Lithuania (2.6 %) and Greece (2.6 %) the lowest.
This has not changed much after the crisis: the same three countries have the highest shares
while Slovenia, Greece and Lithuania are on the lower end of the ranking.
Graph 3: CIT revenues to GDP, EU-Member States, 1995, 2000, 2007, 2012
8,0
7,0
6,0
5,0
4,0
3,0
2,0
1,0
0,0
Malta
Cyprus
Luxemburg
Czech Republic
Belgium
Denmark
Sweden
UK
Italy
Portugal
Germany
Slovakia
Ireland
Austria
France
Finland
Romania
Spain
Poland
Netherlands
Bulgaria
Croatia
Latvia
Estonia
Hungary
Lithuania
Slovenia
Greece
1995
2000
2007
2012
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
A1.4
A
CLOSER LOOK ON THE DEVELOPMENTS IN THE
EU.
The reduction of the average rate was accompanied by a decrease of both the lowest and
the highest rate in the EU.
Graph 4 plots the statutory rates across the EU in 1995, 2000,
2007 and 2015. Member states are ranked by their statutory CIT rate in 2014. Graph 5 shows,
apart from the EU-28 average, the evolution of the highest and the lowest statutory rates that
were observed in the current EU, as well as those of the averages for other subgroups of the
EU. Over the period 1995-2014, the EU-28 average rate declined by 12 percentage points
from 35 % to 23 %. The highest rate was reduced from 56.8%
49
in Germany in 1995 to 38.0
% in France in 2014. The lowest headline rate, 19.6 % in Hungary in 1995, decreased to 10 %
in Bulgaria in 2014. Germany held the highest rate until the corporate tax reform of 2001, in
which year the German rate undercut the Italian one, which was at 40.3%. After a reduction in
Italy in 2003, the German rate again was highest until the reform of 2008. In that year,
48
49
In 2000, Estonia limited the Corporate Income Tax to distributed profits.
Including the local trade tax.
3
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0036.png
statutory rates in all other Member States had been lowered below the Maltese level of 35 %.
Only in 2012 the increase of the surcharge in France took the combined rate above the
Maltese level
50
. For the period 1995 – 2001 the lowest corporate tax rate, national rate plus
local taxes, was to be found in Hungary at a level of 19.6%. In 2002 Lithuania reduced its rate
to 15%, which was the lowest in that year. One year later, Ireland
51
reduced the headline rate
to 12.5 %, which became the lowest. Since 2005 the lowest rate available is 10%. This rate
was available in Cyprus (2005-2012) and is in force in Bulgaria since 2006. All in all, the
maximum rate was reduced by 18.8 percentage points and the minimum rate by 9.6%.
Graph 4: Statutory CIT rates, EU-Member States, 1995, 2000, 2007, 2014
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
France
Malta
Belgium
Portugal
Italy
Germany
Spain
Luxemburg
Greece
Netherlands
Austria
Denmark
Slovakia
Sweden
Estonia
UK
Hungary
Croatia
Finland
Czech Republic
Poland
Slovenia
Romania
Latvia
Lithuania
Ireland
Cyprus
Bulgaria
1995
2000
2007
2014
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
50
Please note that the highest rate in France only applies to enterprises with a turnover of more than EUR
250 million and that the Maltese system of imputation and refunds is not taken into account.
51
Until 2003, Ireland applied a 10 % CIT rate to qualifying manufacturing and services companies.
4
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0037.png
Graph 5: Statutory CIT rates, maximum EU-28, unweighted averages EU-28, EA-18, EU-15
and NMS, minimum EU-28, 1995-2014
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
max
EU-28
EU-15
NMS
EA-18
min
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
Headline rates of different Member States have come closer to each other.
In the period
1995 – 2001 the spread, the difference between the highest and the lowest corporate tax rate
was reduced from 37 percentage points to 20 percentage points, mainly by the reductions in
Germany. In later years reductions of the lowest rates increased the spread between minimum
and maximum again. In the years 2007 – 2011 it stabilised at 25 percentage points. After that
year, due to the increases in France, it rose again to 28 percentage points. This is plotted in
graph 4. This graph also contains the standard deviation of the rates. This measure for the
spread is less sensitive to the behaviour of the highest and the lowest rate. Its trajectory
corroborates the image that the spread has been reduced until 2001, but rebounded to a level
below that of 1995.
Graph 4: Measures of the spread of CIT-rates, EU-28
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
maximum-minimum
standard deviation (right hand scale)
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014) and Commission services
The reduction of the average corporate income tax rate in the period 1995-2014 was
supported by almost all Member States. The fastest reduction took place in the period
5
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0038.png
2000-2005, when 23 countries reduced their rates. In the period 2005-2010, the number
of Member States reducing the rate decreased, to decrease even further after the crisis.
This is one of the causes of the levelling off of the reduction of the average rate. This is
shown in table 1 and graph 5. Only in two Member States (France and Hungary), the rate was
higher in 2014 than in 1995. In Malta, the rate didn't change over the period under
consideration. Looking at five year periods, we see that in the period 2000-2005 both the
number of countries reducing the rate and the average reduction were high. Only the UK,
Sweden, Slovenia, Malta and Spain did not change the rate in that period. After the crisis still
six Member States reduced the rate (the UK, Sweden, Finland, Slovenia, Netherlands and
Denmark), but that was balanced by the same number of countries increasing the rate (Greece,
France, Cyprus, Luxembourg, Portugal and Slovakia).
52
Table 1: Number of Member States increasing and decreasing the statutory CIT rate
1995-2000
Number reducing the rate
Number increasing the rate
Change of (unweighted)
average rate
13
4
-2.9
2000-2005
23
0
-6.8
2005-2010
14
2
-2.1
2010-2014
6
6
-0.3
Total 1995-2014
25
2
-12.0
Source: Commission services
Graph 5: Change of average CIT-rate and number of Member States increasing or
decreasing rates
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
-2,0
-0,5
-1,0
-1,5
0,0
1,0
0,5
# reducing rate
# increasing rate
change of average rate (rhs)
Source: Commission Services
52
E.g. Chatelin and Peyrat: Are small countries leaders of the European tax competition?, Documents de
travail du Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne 2008.58
6
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0039.png
Reductions in the new member states were larger and started earlier than in the old
member states.
In the literature on this subject, it is stipulated that tax competition is related
to the openness of individual economies and the integration of the different economies. In this
respect, the enlargement of the EU in 2004 could have caused an increase of the tax
competition as the economies of the existing EU-15 states and the New Member States have
become more open to each other and more integrated. We have already seen in graph 5 that
the strongest reductions of CIT rates took place before the enlargement. In table 2 the
evolution of the average CIT rate has been decomposed between the 'old' EU-15 and the New
Member States. Overall, the New Member States reduced their rates stronger than the EU-15.
They also started earlier. In the period 2000-2005 the reduction in the NMS was larger than
that in the EU-15. In 2005-2010 the reductions in the EU-15 were larger than in the new
member states.
Table 2: Change of (unweighted) average statutory CIT rate, 1995-2014
1995-2000
EU-15
NMS
EU-28
-2.7
-3.3
-2.9
2000-2005
-5.3
-8.4
-6.8
2005-2010
-2.7
-1.3
-2.1
2010-2014
-0.6
0.2
-0.3
Total 1995-2014
-11.3
-12.8
-12.0
Source: Taxation Trends in the European Union (2014)
A1.5.
BASE BROADENING
:
CHANGES IN CAPITAL ALLOWANCES
Base broadening has been less ubiquitous than rate reduction: Thirteen Member States
have broadened the corporate tax base by reducing depreciation allowances, seven
narrowed the base by increasing them and one reduced allowances for one type of
investments and increased them for the other two types. The number of Member States
increasing allowances for investments in intangibles exceeds the number reducing these
allowances.
Countries reducing the statutory Corporate Income Tax rate sometimes increase
the tax base to partly compensate the revenues foregone. Devereux et al. use the development
of depreciation allowances for machinery as an indicator for the broadening or narrowing of
the corporate tax base. For the EU data on these allowances can be found in the yearly ZEW
publication
53
on effective tax corporate tax levels. Table 3 shows the number of Member State
changing depreciation allowance rules and the average change of the depreciation
allowance
54
. A reduction of the allowance means a broadening of the tax base. Reduction of
the depreciation allowance has been used by roughly half of the Member States: thirteen
Member States reduced the allowance for at least one type of investment: Denmark, Germany,
Ireland, Greece, Spain, France, Italy, Malta, Austria, Poland, Romania, Slovenia and the UK.
On the other hand, seven Member States increased the generosity of the allowance regime:
Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Croatia, Cyprus, Lithuania, Hungary, Slovakia and Finland.
Hungary allowed more depreciation of machinery and intangibles, but reduced depreciation of
buildings. Estonia limited the corporate income tax to distributed profits in 2000. Until 2010,
the number of Member States increasing allowances roughly balanced the number of Member
States decreasing them. After 2010, base broadening became more popular. The desire of
administrations to attract investments in intangibles is reflected by the fact that more Member
States increased allowances for this type of investment.
53
54
ZEW (2014): Effective Tax Levels Using the Devereux/Griffiths Methodology, Final Report 2014,
Project for the EU Commission TAXUD/ 2013/ CC/120.
The value of the allowances is calculated as the Net Present Value of the allowed depreciation for tax
purposes.
7
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0040.png
Some Member States used accelerated depreciation to try to increase investments after
the crisis.
Germany, the Netherlands, Austria and Finland introduced accelerated depreciation
for machinery in 2009 to counter the reduction of investments in the crisis. After two or three
years these measures were withdrawn.
Base broadening is more common in large economies than in smaller ones. Reduction of
allowances is the strongest for buildings, less strong for machinery and the weakest for
intangibles.
On average, the depreciation allowances for buildings have been reduced,
indicating base broadening.. The trend for the other types of capital depends on the way the
average is being calculated. For machinery, the unweighted average of the allowance has
remained almost stable, and the weighted
55
average has declined. The unweighted average
allowance for intangibles even increased, while the weighted average has declined. All this
indicates that base broadening has been stronger in countries with a higher GDP than in
countries with a lower one.
Table 3: Number of Member States changing capital allowances and the change of the
allowances
1998-
2000
Industrial buildings
Number reducing the allowance (base broadening)
Number increasing the allowance (base narrowing)
Change of unweighted average allowance
Change of weighted average allowance
Machinery
Number reducing the allowance (base broadening)
Number increasing the allowance (base narrowing)
Change of unweighted average allowance
Change of weighted average allowance
Intangible assets
Number reducing the allowance (base broadening)
Number increasing the allowance (base narrowing)
Change of unweighted average allowance
Change of weighted average allowance
One of the above
Number reducing allowances (base broadening)
Number increasing allowances (base narrowing)
Number increasing allowances for one type and
reducing for other types
3
3
0
8
7
1
5
4
0
6
2
0
13
7
1
0
3
1.8
0.0
2
4
1.0
-2.1
0
0
0.0
0.4
1
1
0.6
-0.4
3
6
3.4
-2.0
1
1
0.2
-0.1
7
5
1.6
-1.4
4
4
0.4
-0.7
6
2
-1.8
-3.5
11
7
0.4
-5.7
2
2
0.7
-4.0
4
3
-2.0
-2.0
4
1
-1.6
-4.4
3
2
-0.1
-1.9
10
5
-3.0
-12.3
2000-
2005
2005-
2010
2010-
2014
Total
1998-2014
Source: Commission services, based on ZEW
55
GDP-weighted.
8
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0041.png
A1.6
T
HE EVOLUTION OF EFFECTIVE TAX RATES
Due to the reduction of the statutory rate, the effective average tax rate and the effective
marginal tax rate fell, but to a lesser extent than the statutory rates.
Looking at the
taxation of return on investments, the statutory rate and depreciation allowances are not the
only determinants of the amount of payable tax. For instance, the way in which investment is
financed - by retained earnings, new equity or debt – can influence the amount of payable tax.
To grasp some of these differences, measures for the effective average tax rate (EATR) and
the effective marginal tax rate (EMTR) have been constructed. The EATR is the share of
taxes to be paid in the return on an investment with a
return
exceeding the cost of capital. The
EMTR signifies the share of taxes on the marginal investment, which generates no net return
over the cost of capital. Data for these two indicators for all EU Member States and a number
of other countries are published yearly by ZEW.
In the literature it is assessed that the statutory rate mainly influences profit shifting, while
discrete investment decisions depend on the effective average tax rate and capital flows
depend on the effective marginal tax rate. In 1998
56
, the average EATR was 5.1 percentage
points lower than the average
statutory
rate (29.1 % and 34.2 %, respectively) and the EMTR
13.5 % (at a rate of 20.7 %) In table 3 it is shown that as statutory rates declined, also the
effective tax rates have been reduced, but to a lesser extent than the statutory rate. The
difference between the statutory rate and the effective average rate has been reduced by 3.1
percentage points and the difference between the effective marginal tax rate and the statutory
rate by 6.2 percentage points. Not in all Member States the difference between statutory and
effective rates fell. In Belgium, Estonia, Hungary and Portugal, it increased and in Malta it did
not change.
It is in the line of expectations that effective rates will fall when statutory rates do and that the
absolute reduction will be less for the effective rates. It is, however, not immediately clear if
the different trajectories are an indication of base broadening. The statutory rate is clearly part
of the effective rates. As the indicators used are averaged across types of investment
(buildings, machinery, intangibles) and ways of financing (retained earnings, new equity,
debt), the evolution of the effective rates in absence of any change of the base is not clear-cut.
Table 3: Change of average CIT rate, effective average tax rate, effective marginal tax rate, 1998 –
2014 in percentage points, EU-28
1998-2000
CIT rate
57
EATR
EMTR
-2.0
-1.7
-1.9
2000-2005
-6.1
-4.3
-1.4
2005-2010
-2.1
-2.0
-2.5
2010-2014
-0.3
0.1
0.8
Total 1998-2014
-10.4
-8.0
-4.9
Source: ZEW and Commission services
A1.7
P
REFERENTIAL REGIMES
.
The number of Member States with an IP box started to increase in 2007. In 2014 ten
Member States offer a special CIT rate for the proceeds of R&D.
Apart from changing the
tax rate and base, countries can compete by many other means. A common measure taken by
Member States is the introduction of a preferential regime for profits originating from the
56
57
1998 is the first year of the ZEW publications
To keep the table consistent, in this table CIT rate data from ZEW are being used. These differ slightly
from those published in Taxation Trends in EU-Member States
9
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0042.png
development or the purchase of intellectual property (IP). Although modalities differ
58
, the
common feature is that profits derived from the use of intellectual property (IP) are being
taxed at a reduced rate. This type of system existed in France and Ireland in 1998. Hungary
introduced an IP-box in 2003 followed by Netherlands and Belgium in 2007 and by
Luxemburg and Spain in 2008. Finally, Malta, Cyprus, the UK and Portugal took likewise
measures in 2010, 2012, 2013 and 2014, respectively, while Ireland abolished its rule in 2010.
The so-called IP box offers a rate with a reduction
59
with respect to the headline CIT rate. The
lowest reduction is 50 % in Hungary and Portugal, while Malta offers a reduction of 100 %.
The rise in the number of IP-boxes occurred when the reduction of corporate tax rates
decelerated. It should be noted that these boxes are under scrutiny of the European
Commission. In Graph 7 the number of countries involved and the average discount is
reproduced.
Graph 6: Number of Member States offering IP boxes and average reduction of rates
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
120%
100%
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
number of Member States
average reduction (right hand scale)
Source: Commission Services
A1.8
T
HE RELATION BETWEEN
GDP
AND STATUTORY RATES
According to economic theory, larger countries are less vulnerable to tax competition
than smaller countries.
Several authors
60
point at a relation between size and tax
competition. For large economies the necessity to compete for foreign investments would be
less and the loss from rate reductions would be higher than in smaller countries. Therefore,
rates in larger countries would be higher than in smaller countries. To shed some light on this
hypothesis, graph 8 plots the level of the corporate tax rate against GDP in 1995.
In 1995 Germany and Italy dominate the image.
Looking at the picture for 1995, the high
rates in Italy and Germany immediately meet the eye. For the rest, the image is mixed. A
number of (future) Member States with low GDP have high statutory corporate tax rates.
58
59
60
Data based on the information in JRC/TAXUD (2015)
For instance, the rate of the Dutch 'innovation box' is 5 %. Compared to the headline rate of 25 %, this
is a reduction of 80%.
E.g. Slemrod (2004) and Chatelais and Peyrat (2008)
10
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0043.png
Graph 8: Relation of GDP and statutory CIT rate, 1995
Graph 9: Relation of GDP and statutory CIT rate, 2013
Source: Commission services
11
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0044.png
In 2013, smaller countries seem to have lower rates than larger countries.
Especially the
New Member States have decreased their ranking
61
. Graph 9 shows the situation for 2013. A
line has been drawn around the New Member States. The 2013 situation shows another
outlier. Malta, that did not change its rate, appears among the countries with the highest
corporate rates. For the rest, New Member States that had relatively high rates in 1995 now
are below the average (e.g. Czech Republic and Poland) or at the lower end (Bulgaria) of the
distribution.
61
With the exception of Malta.
12
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0045.png
A
NNEX
2
A
PPLICATION OF THE
C
OMMISSION
R
ECOMMENDATION ON AGGRESSIVE
T
AX
P
LANNING AND ON
M
EASURES TO
E
NCOURAGE
T
HIRD
C
OUNTRIES TO
A
PPLY
M
INIMUM
S
TANDARDS OF
G
OOD
G
OVERNANCE IN
T
AX
M
ATTERS
The purpose this paper is to provide factual information relating to the application of the
Recommendations on aggressive tax planning and on measures intended to encourage
third countries to apply minimum standards of good governance in tax matters, which
contributed to the Commission Action Plan in 2012
62
.
In response to the Recommendations, the Council invited Member States to consider the
appropriateness of incorporating a General Anti Abuse Rule, such as that suggested in the
Recommendation on aggressive tax planning, in their national legislation and invited
consideration of whether developing a European list of third country non-cooperative
jurisdictions is appropriate (ECOFIN conclusions of 14 May 2013 and European Council
conclusions of 22 May 2013).
The application of the Recommendations has been discussed in the Platform for Tax good
Governance, which is composed of representatives of the 28 Member States and of 15
organisations representing business, civil society and tax practitioners. One of the
purposes of the Platform of good tax governance is to assist the Commission in preparing
its report on the application of the Recommendations. This was one amongst the priorities
in the agreed work programme of the Platform. Accordingly, the Platform held
discussions on both Recommendations at its meetings on 16 October 2013, 6 February
2014, 10th June 214, 19
th
December 2014 and 2
nd
March 2015.
The detailed work of the Platform and all related documents are available on the dedicated
webpage
of DG Taxation and Customs Union.
The purpose of the
Recommendation regarding measures intended to encourage third
countries to apply minimum standards of good governance in tax matters
is to
increase the overall effectiveness of the measures taken by each Member State in relation
to third countries not meeting the minimum standards of good governance in tax matters
(transparency, exchange of information, and fair tax competition). To this effect, the
Recommendation provides criteria making it possible to identify third countries not
meeting these minimum standards, and lists a series of actions that Member States may
take in relation to such countries.
The work programme of the Platform for tax good governance provides that '
The Platform
will discuss and suggest a mechanism or process to ensure consistency in the establishment
and monitoring of the black lists. Where appropriate, the Platform can suggest follow-up or
complementary steps to the current Recommendation, both regulatory and organisational,
with a view to contributing to its essential goal: global promotion of the EU standards of
good governance in tax matters
'.
The purpose of the
Recommendation on Aggressive Tax Planning
is to better enable
Member States to address aggressive tax planning by reducing double non-taxation and
62
An Action Plan to strengthen the fight against tax fraud and tax evasion (COM(2012)722),
Recommendation regarding measures intended to encourage third countries to apply minimum
standards of good governance in tax matters (C(2012) 8805) and Recommendation on aggressive tax
planning (C(2012) 8806).
1
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
ensuring a minimum level of protection across the EU MS by the adoption of a general
anti-abuse rule (GAAR) taking into account the limits imposed by Union law.
The work programme of the Platform provides that 'The
Platform will discuss how a
common interpretation of the GAAR recommended by the Commission can best be
ensured. Where needed, the Platform will discuss how the application of the GAAR relates
to tax incentives introduced by individual Member States.
The Platform will discuss possible ways to implement a tax treaty clause which ensures
that treaty provisions aimed at avoiding double taxation do not enable double non-
taxation. It will also discuss best-practices that could assist Member States in the
practical application of such clauses'.
The outcome of the work of the Platform so far is reflected in the discussion paper
Platform/13/2014/EN/rev2
(see annex 3). Based on factual elements, discussions held in
the Platform, and conclusions discussed within the Platform, this paper reviews how the
Recommendations have been followed-up by Member States and mentions some possible
further steps.
_________________________
2
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0047.png
A
NNEX
3
P
LATFORM FOR
T
AX
G
OOD
G
OVERNANCE
PLATFORM FOR TAX GOOD GOVERNANCE
Discussion paper on the follow-up of the Commission
Recommendations of 6 December 2012
Building blocks
Meeting of 2
nd
March 2015
Disclaimer:
This annex 3 is a Commission services working paper prepared by DG TAXUD for discussion
purposes. It does not represent a formal Commission or Commission services position or
policy. The paper is therefore without prejudice to any position which may be taken by the
Commission in the future.
Contact:
Secretariat Platform, Telephone (32-2) 29.55.762
E-mail:
[email protected]
3
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0048.png
1.
I
NTRODUCTION
When adopting its Action plan and two Recommendations
63
, the Commission committed
to report within three years on the application of the Recommendations.
In response to the Recommendations, the Council invited Member States to consider the
appropriateness of incorporating a General Anti Abuse Rule, such as that suggested in the
Recommendation on aggressive tax planning, in their national legislation and invited
consideration of whether developing a European list of third country non-cooperative
jurisdictions is appropriate (ECOFIN conclusions of 14 May 2013 and European Council
conclusions of 22 May 2013).
One of the purposes of the Platform of good tax governance is to assist the Commission in
preparing its report
64
on the application of the Recommendations. This was one amongst
the priorities in the agreed work programme of the Platform. Accordingly, the Platform
held discussions on both Recommendations at its meetings on 16 October 2013, 6
February 2014, 10th June 214 and 19th December 2014.
All Member States support tackling tax avoidance and tax evasion, but there are
differences of opinion on how that can be achieved.
The present document aims at preparing the field for this Commission report on the
application of the two Recommendations. The paper is structured around building blocks
and contains some suggestions for the way forward. Members of the Platform are invited
to provide comments at the meeting. Written comments are also welcome.
2.
OF THE
R
ECOMMENDATION REGARDING MEASURES INTENDED TO
ENCOURAGE THIRD COUNTRIES TO APPLY MINIMUM STANDARDS OF GOOD
GOVERNANCE IN TAX MATTERS
A
PPLICATION
The purpose of the Recommendation is to increase the overall effectiveness of the
measures taken by each Member State in relation to third counties not meeting the
minimum standards of good governance in tax matters (transparency, exchange of
information, and fair tax competition). To this effect, the Recommendation provides
criteria making it possible to identify third countries not meeting these minimum
standards, and lists a series of actions that Member States may take in relation to such
countries.
The Commission services intend to report on the basis of:
- the factual elements contained in the discussion paper presented to the Platform for its
meeting on 19 December (Platform/11/2014/EN),
- the discussions held in the Platform,
63
64
An Action Plan to strengthen the fight against tax fraud and tax evasion (COM(2012)722),
Recommendation regarding measures intended to encourage third countries to apply minimum
standards of good governance in tax matters (C(2012) 8805) and Recommendation on aggressive tax
planning (C(2012) 8806).
Formally, DG Taxation and Customs Union (TAXUD) will prepare a draft in consultation with other
Commission services, for consideration by the College.
4
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0049.png
- and to draw possible conclusions on how the Recommendations have been followed-up
by MS. Such conclusions may in fact go further, and outline ways of making the content
of the Recommendations more easy to apply.
This structure is the one followed under each section (criteria used, lists, etc.).
It should be noted that no Member State has so far reported having fully followed the
Recommendation.
The Recommendation regarding measures intended to encourage third countries to apply
minimum standards of good governance in tax matters ('tax havens' Recommendation)
was discussed at the Platform meetings of 16 October 2013, 6 February 2014, 10 June
2014 and 19 December 2014. A questionnaire, to which all MS replied, was circulated to
allow a comparison across Member States (MS) on criteria applied and measures
triggered.
4.1
Criteria used
2.1.1. Factual elements
Information based on document Platform/11/2014/EN
Member States have reported using various types of criteria, sometimes in combination,
for assessing the tax systems of other countries. However these criteria may be used for
other purposes than establishing lists.
Criteria provided for by the Recommendation
Compliance with transparency and exchange of information standards
65
: this
criterion is used by 18 MS (BE, BG, CY, CZ, DE, EE, EL, ES, FR, HR, IE, IT,
LT, LV, PL, PT, SE, UK), out of which 13 MS use it for blacklisting purposes
66
only one MS (DE) uses it as sole criterion for blacklisting purposes, and one MS
(UK) uses it for a different listing system.
Absence of harmful tax measures
67
: this criterion is used by 12 MS (BE, BG, CY,
EE, EL, HR, IT, LT, LV, PL, PT, SE), but not all for blacklisting purposes. All 12
MS use the "absence of harmful tax measures" criterion in combination with the
"transparency and exchange of information" criterion.
Additional or different criteria
Tax level: 8 MS (BE, BG, EL, FI, LT, LV, PT, SI) report using the level of
taxation for blacklisting purposes
68
. Out of these 8 MS, 6 (BE, BG, EL, LT, LV,
PT) combine it with the two criteria of the Recommendation, and 2 MS (FI and
65
66
67
68
Type of criterion recommended in Commission Recommendation C(2012) 8805 point 3a
Out of these, 3 MS have no list system (CY, CZ, IE), one use it for white list (SE) and one has another
listing system (UK)
Type of criterion recommended in Commission Recommendation C(2012) 8805 point 3b
4 other MS (AT, CY, HU, SE) refer to the level of taxation for other purposes than blacklisting.
5
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0050.png
SI) use the level of taxation as sole criterion. The tax rate/level threshold varies
from 4%
69
(BG) to 15%
70
(FI); it is expressed either as a fixed percentage or by
reference to the tax rate of the MS concerned.
Other criteria: existence of a double tax convention, an exchange of information
agreement or a convention on mutual assistance (13 MS: BG, EE, EL, ES, FI,
FR, HR, HU, LV, PL, SI, SK, UK), non-EU or non-EEA countries (8 MS: BG,
CZ, EL, FI, HU, LV, SI, SK), artificiality of transactions (RO), automatic
exchange of information and least developed countries (UK). These criteria are
used for blacklisting, whitelisting or for other purposes.
2.1.2. Discussions in the Platform
Transparency and exchange of information
(TEOI). Platform members agreed that
the work of the Global Forum should form part of any assessment of the Transparency
and Exchange of Information criteria under the Recommendation, and Platform
members foresee no major practical or administrative difficulties in applying this
approach in practice. Several MS take the Global Forum rating into account,
complemented by their own evaluation based on their experience of effective
exchange of Information with the jurisdiction concerned.
Harmful tax measures
Platform members recognised the usefulness of this criterion;
they agreed that the Code criteria and existing Code assessments should be used as a
benchmark for the purpose of applying the fair tax competition criterion of the
Recommendation. This is also used in relation to discussions with some third
countries (CH, LI). However, assessing this criterion appears onerous in terms of
workload, especially for small Member States, and some suggested that this could be
solved by providing or sharing reliable information.
Possible additional criteria
o
Platform members agreed that existing intra-EU tax standards and regulations
are important as benchmarks prior to promoting tax standards and regulations
towards third countries, and reviewing internal standards is needed to raising
the bar in the context of recent international developments;
o
Various views were expressed on the tax rate/effective level of taxation
criterion used by some Member States. Some consider it should not be taken
into account in relation to third countries since it is not currently applied within
the EU, some others suggest that this should be further considered, in the light
of recent OECD and EU developments.
69
70
40% of BG corporate tax rate (10%)= 4%
3/4 of FI corporate tax rate (20%) = 15%. The FI domestic tax law includes a regime on special
controlled foreign corporations (CFC) by virtue of which a “grey list” is established over countries, in
which the tax burden is deemed to significantly differ from the corporate tax paid by Finnish
companies. The level of tax actually paid in a non-EU tax treaty country is deemed substantially lower
as compared to the corresponding Finnish tax on the income if the foreign tax is,
on average,
lower
than 3/4 of the corresponding Finnish tax. However, an entity in a grey list country cannot be
considered to be a CFC as long as the entity itself pays taxes which are 3/5 or more of the taxes that
would have been paid in Finland.
6
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0051.png
2.1.3. Possible conclusions on criteria
For comments by Platform members
Recommendation C(2012) 8805 contains 2 sets of criteria. Ten MS (out of 18)
already comply with these two criteria, since for listing purposes they use the
presence of harmful tax measures criterion in combination with the one on
transparency and exchange of information. The other MS apply other criteria like
the tax level, either alone, or in combination with one or both criteria of the
Recommendation.
The 2 criteria provided by the Recommendation (transparency and exchange of
information; fair tax competition) are the most relevant for assessing the good
governance criteria. They may be supplemented by criteria on effective
cooperation (i.e bilateral/multilateral instruments).
The Commission services might also suggest to give further consideration, in the
light of OECD and EU developments, to the relevance of other criteria, such as
the level of taxation, in particular towards those jurisdictions having no taxation
at all. In addition, since the adoption of the Recommendation, automatic
exchange of information has become the norm, it would be logical to use this also
as a criterion.
4.2
Lists
2.2.1. Factual elements
Information based on document Platform/11/2014/EN
Out of 28 replies received, 18 MS have a (black/white/other) listing system, 10 MS
having no list at all.
C
ONTENT OF LISTS
1 - Blacklisted jurisdictions
The number of black listed jurisdictions ranges from 0 in DE to 85 in PT. The use
of the criteria mentioned under point 1.1
supra
gives the following results.
Transparency and exchange of information
The 13 MS (BE, BG, DE, EE, EL, ES, FR, HR, IT, LT, LV, PL, PT)) using this
criterion (solely or in combination with others) list between 0 (DE) and 85(PT)
jurisdictions (see
table 1).
Only DE uses solely this criterion.
Harmful tax measures
The 10 MS (BE, BG, EE, EL, HR, IT, LT, LV, PL, PT) using this criterion in
combination with the first one result in listing between 24 (BE) and 85 (PT)
7
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0052.png
jurisdictions. However these are not always the same (see
table 2).
Amongst the 4 MS (EE, HR, IT, PL) using only the 2 criteria of the
Recommendation (see
table 3),
there are some discrepancies: 31 jurisdictions are
blacklisted by these 4 MS, 7 by 3 of them, 20 jurisdictions are blacklisted by 2 MS,
and 27 by only one (not always the same MS). In total, EE has blacklisted 55
jurisdictions, HR 50, IT 68 and PL 39. If we compare the 4 MS (EE, HR, IT, PL)
that use only both criteria from the Recommendation, to the 2 MS (FI, SI) using
the tax level criterion only, the first group (Recommendation criteria) lists between
39 (PL) and 68 (IT) jurisdictions, while FI and SI list 15 and 19 jurisdictions
respectively. 10 jurisdictions blacklisted by FI and/or SI had not been blacklisted
by any of the 4 MS using both Recommendation criteria only.
Level of taxation
The 6 MS (BE, BG, EL, LT, LV, PT) using this criterion in combination with those
of the Recommendation result in listing together 10 jurisdictions (see
table 4).
However, 22 jurisdictions are listed by 5 of them, 12 jurisdictions are listed
together by 4 of them, 13 by 3 MS, 18 jurisdictions are blacklisted by 2 MS, and 41
by only one (not always the same MS). In total, BE has blacklisted 24 jurisdictions,
BG 45, EL 58, LT 60, LV 62 and PT 85.
The 2 MS (FI, SI) using solely the level of taxation for blacklisting purposes list 15
and 19 jurisdictions (see
table 5).
These various points show a wide range of differences between MS' evaluations
when using a comparable set of criteria.
2 - White lists
There are 5 MS having whitelists (IT, EE, LT, SE, SK).
However, the IT is used for withholding tax exemptions on interest payments on
bonds issued by the state banks or quoted companies and not for anti-avoidance
issues. It is therefore not suggested to be considered for the purpose of this process.
Estonia (EE) has a white list of countries not considered as low tax jurisdictions as
well as a blacklist. They are both used for CFC and non-deductibility of cost
purposes. It is worth to note that EE white lists countries such as Bahrain
(blacklisted by 8 MS), FYROM (blacklisted by 2 MS), the Isle of Man (blacklisted
by 9 MS), Jersey (blacklisted by 6 MS), Singapore (blacklisted by 4 MS),
Switzerland (blacklisted by 2 MS) or the United Arab Emirates (blacklisted by 8
MS).
SE has reported having a white list linked to CFC rules: in case a CFC is
established in a white listed country, it is not necessary for the tax administration to
perform the CFC-rules tests.
8
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0053.png
3 - Other listing system
The UK categories for offshore penalties considers the efficiency with which tax
information is received from third countries.
71
Category 1 includes those countries
from which information is received automatically, Category 2 includes those from
which information is received on request whilst Category 3 includes countries
which are not compliant with EOI on Request as well as those where exchange of
information arrangements are not in place.
M
ANAGEMENT OF
MS'
LISTS
The 18 MS having lists indicated they were publicly available and provided
links to their websites;
Very few MS have a periodical review of their list, which takes place each
year (EL, FR) or every 2 years (BE). The other 15 MS review their lists on
an ad hoc basis. However, several updating issues have been identified.
2.2.2. Discussion in the Platform
Non-MS members were in favour of a single EU blacklist given the difficulty in
their view to achieve coherence between 28 MS blacklists, and in order to have a
level playing field for all companies in all MS. One MS suggested that the
Commission should assess the compatibility of Member States lists with EU law.
However, Platform members welcomed the comparison of various lists from MS
and the Commission services' suggestion to publish a consolidated version on the
Platform website. They also recognised the need to improve consistency of
assessments made under similar criteria.
On transparency, Platform members recognised the usefulness of keeping lists up-
to-date on a regular (i.e. at least annual) basis. They noted that this could be
resource-intensive for some MS, and called for an appropriate procedure.
2.2.3. Possible conclusions
For comments by Platform members
71
Those MS having no listing process have not reported they are considering
adopting one.
The Commission services might suggest solutions to improve the consistency of
The UK does not consider its differentiated penalty regime to be a black list since it only applies higher
penalties to individuals who are found to have been non-compliant in their activities in particular
countries rather triggering any measures of general application (e.g. withholding taxes).
9
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0054.png
assessments of similar criteria.
This could include sharing information on:
- effectiveness of exchange of information mechanisms with the jurisdiction
concerned, in particular for those jurisdictions not having yet passed the phase 2
review of the Global Forum;
- the presence of potentially harmful tax measures detected by MS or by the
Commission services.
Possible mechanisms could range from informal/multilateral ones (between MS
and with Commission services), or/and with some monitoring by the Platform or
by an institutionalised instance (such as an appropriate Council group).
The Commission services might also suggest that such monitoring mechanisms
could also cover the updating of MS lists, to ensure that any update from a MS
would be reflected in due time in the list consolidated for publication on the
TAXUD webpage.
4.3
Measures applied towards third countries
2.3.1. Factual elements
The Recommendation contains a series of positive and negative measures (de-
listing/listing with a reference to the Recommendation, initiation/termination of
double tax conventions, technical assistance…) that MS may apply towards third
countries, depending on whether they comply with or are committed to the minimum
standards of good governance.
Member States have not reported using two of the measures (treaty renegotiation or
incentives). They have however reported using on an individual basis a number of
other tax measures, such as non-deductibility of costs (11 MS), CFC rules (8 MS), and
measures related to withholding taxes (10 MS).
2.3.2. Discussion in the Platform
Platform members recognised the general relevance of the measures provided in the
Recommendation as a mean to convince third countries to adopt minimum standards
of good governance. However, some Platform members expressed reservations on
granting incentives to jurisdictions not yet complying with minimum requirements,
while other members stressed the need to strengthen EU assistance to developing
countries on policy making, administrative support and capacity development.
Platform members noted the variety of measures currently applied by MS, with 3 main
categories (non-deductibility of costs, CFC, withholding taxes).
Platform members recognised that the threat of being collectively blacklisted in
combination with positive measures should often suffice to convince most third
countries to comply with such standards. It was understood that practical application
10
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0055.png
of the measures needs to be proportionate and to allow flexibility based on a case by
case assessment of both the seriousness of the non-compliance and of interests other
than tax good governance. In this respect, some Platform members expressed concerns
on the difficulty to apply on an individual basis negative measures against a big
powerful jurisdiction because of the risk of countermeasures, or that countermeasures
should not undermine progress on Automatic Exchange of Information.
The Recommendation does not require coordinated actions but some discussions in the
Platform underlined that collective/coordinated actions would be more effective than
individual actions in relation to third countries. A coordinated action could bring some
of the most problematic jurisdictions to amend certain practices.
2.3.3. Possible conclusions
For comments by Platform members
MS have not reported having taken additional actions as a follow-up to the
Recommendation. However, incidentally and as a result of their existing
rules, some MS comply
de facto
with some of the criteria and a few
measures contained in the Recommendation.
The Commission services note that, while aiming at the same goals as those
of the Recommendation, the fact that MS do not follow the same approach
leads to additional work. They should at least cooperate to convince third
countries to comply with the minimum standards of good governance in tax
matters. The lack of appetite from MS to act collectively against non-
compliant countries seems to be justified by 3 main reasons: the lack of
resources to assess third countries' tax regimes, the lack of willingness of
some MS to take action against non-compliant countries, and the wish of
MS to keep a margin of manoeuver and to decide what appropriate
measures to apply to third countries.
The Commission services note that a variety of MS measures apply to third
countries without an overall consistency in relation to the minimum
standards of good governance, and that some non-targeted third countries
operate harmful tax measures. Based on experience shared with Platform
members, the Commission services consider that limited collective action
could be sufficient to convince these third countries to comply with the
minimum of good governance. Efficiency of such collective action also
relies on its visibility.
The Commission services may therefore suggest an initiative for further
action, aiming at third countries' effective compliance with minimum
standards of good governance in tax matters (and further standards if
necessary) in their relations with EU MS. This initiative would provide for
further practical assistance on how to apply the content of the
Recommendation. For instance, the Joint Transfer Pricing Forum
successfully agrees on Codes and guidance on how to apply OECD transfer
pricing rules; the Platform could contribute in a similar way. In practical
11
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0056.png
terms such (soft or hard law) initiative could:
o
Provide for an assessment mechanism that could be relied upon by
MS;
o
Propose that MS would promote compliance with the minimum
standards in their relationship with the third countries concerned, so
that collective action may not always be necessary;
o
Foresee minimum measures to be applied collectively, building on
those of the Recommendation;
o
Foresee that MS could individually adopt additional criteria and take
further actions towards the third countries concerned.
4.4
Conclusion
The Commission services will take into consideration the discussion held in the Platform
and written comments from Platform members when moving to the next stage of
preparing a report for consideration by the Commission.
3.
A
PPLICATION OF THE
R
ECOMMENDATION ON
A
GGRESSIVE
T
AX
P
LANNING
The purpose of the Recommendation is to better enable Member States to address
aggressive tax planning by reducing double non-taxation and ensuring a minimum level
of protection across the EU MS by the adoption of a general anti-abuse rule taking into
account the limits imposed by Union law.
The Recommendation was discussed at the Platform meetings of 16 October 2013,
6 February 2014, 10 June 2014 and 19 December 2014.
4.1
Limitation to the application of rules intended to avoid double taxation
3.1.1. Discussion in the Platform
Concerning the clause to prevent double non-taxation in double tax conventions (DTC),
some MS expressed reservations on the scope, which by being too broad in their view
could be used by other contracting parties to tax items that the MS concerned wanted to
exempt. Some suggested that this could be prevented with a more specific (tax or
jurisdiction) scope. Some members mentioned that the systematic inclusion of this clause
would require the renegotiation of all Double Tax Conventions (DTC).
One MS indicated it would introduce a subject to tax clause only on a case by case basis.
Several MS and non-MS members mentioned the parallel OECD work anti-abuse rules in
the DTC; and suggested to wait for the outcome of the OECD work before taking a final
stance.
It seems from the discussion that no MS intends to include the recommended clause in a
foreseeable future.
12
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0057.png
Several members support the CCCTB as part of the solution.
3.1.2. Possible conclusions
For comments by Platform members
Since no MS seems to support the right to tax clause as included in the
Recommendation, the Commission services intend to report that no MS has
decided to follow-up the Recommendation on this point, and that there is a
need to find other ways of treating this issue, having due regard to the
outcome of the OECD on BEPS (notably Actions 6 (Prevent Treaty Abuse)
and 15 (Multilateral Instrument text)).
General Anti Abuse Rule (GAAR)
4.2
A GAAR is a powerful means of protection against novel tax planning schemes and the
common GAAR proposed in the Commission Recommendation takes account of primary
and secondary EU legislation and European Court of Justice (ECJ) rulings.
The Platform agreed to collect more information from MS concerning the GAARs
currently operated at national level. The replies received from MS on the questionnaire
have been summarised in the Discussion Paper
Platform/12/2014/EN
for the 19 December
2014 meeting. It contains useful information on MS having (or not) a GAAR, when
GAARs have been introduced and amended and on the operation of the various GAARs.
A significant new development is the agreement at ECOFIN on 9 December 2014, on a
common anti-abuse rule in the parent-subsidiary directive (PSD).
3.2.1. Factual elements
Information based on document Platform/12/2014/EN
6 MS
72
have indicated to support the Commission Recommendation concerning
the GAAR. Three of them –
EL, RO
and
SK
declare having introduced a
GAAR that has been drafted following the Recommendation on Aggressive Tax
Planning. The other three – HR, IT and PL – are still in the process of following
up on the Recommendation
HR
replied to have the intention to review their existing GAAR, using the
template of the Recommendation.
In
IT,
the Government has been officially charged by the Parliament to
proceed with a general fiscal reform, which will be comprehensive of new
anti-avoidance rule. Article 5 of the law, specifies that this new rule must be
consistent with the EC Recommendation n. 2012/772/UE of 6th December
2012.
PL
has launched a legislative initiative to introduce a GAAR in 2016 that
72
This concerns EL, HR, IT, PL, RO and SK.
13
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0058.png
will take into account the Recommendation.
4 MS are as of yet undecided
73
. They report to still consider the question of
implementing the Commission Recommendation. Some explicitly state that
more clarity would be needed on the working of the Commission
Recommendation and how that interacts with international developments.
The remaining 18 MS report not to see the added value of introducing or
revising their GAAR on the basis of the 2012 Commission Recommendation
74
.
Most of these MS consider that the GAAR or GAAR-equivalent provision that
they currently have works well and/or is very similar in effect to the GAAR
proposed in the Commission Recommendation. Some, such as IE, express
concerns over increased uncertainty in relation to the effectiveness of their tried
and tested provision if it were to be revised. Others, such as LT, are concerned
that MS could interpret the Commission Recommendation differently in the
absence of EU guidance.
3.2.2. Discussion in the Platform
Platform members support improving anti abuse rules support although it is important to
leave some flexibility to MS.
Several Platform members expressed concerns over the GAAR recommended by the
Commission, amongst others: on the manageability of a GAAR by the tax administrations
(complex to use) and by taxpayers (legal uncertainty). Some guidance would be needed on
the application of a GAAR. It was also observed that even if all MS adopt the same
GAAR, different interpretations by different courts may still occur.
3.2.3. Possible conclusions
For comments by Platform members
The follow-up of the recommended GAAR has to be seen in the light of the
agreement on the Parent-Subsidiary directive anti-abuse rule (AAR) and as a
minimum level of protection that should be adopted by all MS.
The Commission services intend to report that MS not having taken additional action
after the Recommendation consider that they already have anti-abuse rules that meet
the objectives of the Commission Recommendation in tackling Aggressive Tax
Planning. This might lead to further consideration and assessment on possible action
to be taken.
_________________________
73
74
This concerns DK, FI, LU and SI.
This concerns AT, BE, BG, CY, CZ, DE, EE, ES, FR, HU, IE, LT, LV, MT, NL, PT, SE and the UK.
14
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0059.png
A
NNEX
4
R
ELATIONS
EU
ACTIONS AND
BEPS
INITIATIVE
BEPS action
Areas for EU action
1. CCCTB: A Holistic Solution to Profit Shifting
Relaunching the CCCTB as a means to address the
current challenges in corporate taxation. A
mandatory CCCTB would include rules in relation
to Controlled Foreign Companies (CFC), interest
deductibility, and permanent establishment (PE).
In the absence of consolidation (first step), the
proposal would also include transfer pricing rules.
Action 3 on Strengthening CFC Rules
Action 4 on Limiting Base Erosion via Interest
Deductions and Other Financial Payments
[Action 6 on Preventing Treaty Abuse]
Action 7 on Preventing the Artificial Avoidance
of PE Status
Action 8-10 on Assuring that Transfer Pricing
Outcomes are in line with Value Creation
Action 1 on Addressing the Tax Challenges of
the Digital Economy is covered by the Action
Plan as a whole.
2. Ensuring Effective Taxation Where Profits are Generated.
2.1 Bringing taxation closer to where profits are
generated and ensuring effective taxation of
profits. Work must continue on elements in the
common base which are linked to the OECD BEPS
project. This would include adjusting PE rules so
that companies cannot artificially avoid having a
taxation presence in Member States in which
they have economic activity, or improving the
CFC rules. The Commission will also consider how
to ensure that EU corporate tax legislation aimed
at preventing double taxation (i.e. the Interest
and Royalties Directive and Parent-Subsidiary
Directive) does not inadvertently lead to double
non-taxation.
Action 7 on Preventing the Artificial Avoidance
of PE Status
Action 3 on Strengthening CFC Rules
Action 2 on Neutralising the Effects of Hybrid
Mismatch Arrangements.
2.2. Improving the Transfer Pricing framework in
Action 8-10 on Assuring that Transfer Pricing
the EU.
Outcomes are in line with Value Creation.
2.3. Linking Preferential Regimes to Where Value Action 5 on Countering Harmful Tax Practices.
is Generated (modified nexus approach as agreed The first work stream of Action 5 relates to
by the Code of Conduct Group). The Commission the review of patent box regimes.
will continue to provide guidance to Member
States on how to implement patent box regimes
in line with the new approach, and carefully
1
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
1537879_0060.png
monitor implementation.
3. Additional Measures for a Better Tax Environment for Business.
3.1. Enabling Cross Border Loss Offset.
3.2. Improving Double Taxation Dispute
Resolution Mechanisms. The Commission will
propose improvements to the current
mechanisms to resolve double taxation disputes
in the EU.
4. Further Progress on Tax Transparency.
Beyond the measures already proposed by the
March Transparency Package, the Commission
has identified further measures to boost
transparency, both in relation to the EU and in
relation to third countries.
Action 5 on Countering Harmful Tax Practices.
The second workstream of Action 5 relates to
spontaneous exchange of information on tax
rulings.
No related BEPS action
Action 14 on Making Dispute Resolution
Mechanisms more Effective addresses the
obstacles that prevent countries from
resolving dispute through the Mutually
Agreed Procedure (MAP).
4.1. Ensuring a more Common Approach to Third Action 5 on Countering Harmful Tax Practices.
Country Non Cooperative Tax Jurisdictions. Action 5 includes a strategy to expand
Beyond the work already done by the Platform participation to non-OECD countries.
on Good Governance, further work in screening
third countries for compliance with tax good
governance standards is also necessary. The Code
of Conduct Group would be the most appropriate
forum to do this.
4.2. Proceeding with work on corporate tax
transparency, including country-by-country
reporting options. This could include making a
limited set of tax information of multinational
companies publicly accessible.
5. EU Tools for Coordination.
5.1. Improving Member States' Coordination on
Tax Audits
5.2. Reforming the Code of Conduct for Business
Taxation and Platform on Tax Good Governance
No BEPS related action.
Action 13 on Re-examining Transfer Pricing
Documentation. However, the OECD reporting
template is only intended for tax authorities
(and not for public disclosure).
No BEPS related action.
2
kom (2015) 0302 - Ingen titel
3